Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Intra-household allocation of family resources and birth order: evidence from France using siblings data

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We examine the effect of birth order on education, occupation, and parental transfers using four cross sections of the French Wealth surveys conducted between 1992 and 2010. Estimates from ordered models confirm the presence of a first born advantage in education and occupation, the latter persisting to a lesser extent after controlling for education. Strikingly, parents are on average more likely to make transfers to first-born children, although the vast majority provides cash or property gifts to all of their children. This first-born advantage in transfers is uncorrelated with the likelihood of having attained a higher education or better occupation. Overall, our findings suggest that in France, the mechanism supporting the first born advantage may not stem from confluence effects or family resource dilution.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. There are also reasons why the last born could, in theory, be favored, e.g., parental earnings increase over the life cycle (hence, there would be fewer resources for the first-born children if households face liquidity constraints) and older mothers are more experienced.

  2. Databases are available free of charge for use in research from the French Data Archives for social sciences (Réseau Quetelet, http://www.reseau-quetelet.cnrs.fr/spip/?lang=en).

  3. The number of respondents is, respectively, 9530 in 1992, 10,168 in 1998, 9692 in 2004, and 15,006 in 2010. In the 2010 Wealth survey, the sample includes 2218 households living in overseas departments. These households were excluded for comparability purposes over the period.

  4. Although we can always identify recomposed families, we treat co-resident half siblings as pure siblings since we do not know which siblings are not those biological children of the reference person. All our results hold when removing recomposed families from the sample.

  5. In the Wealth surveys, there is no information on education for children under 17.

  6. Also, we choose to exclude the few observations (N = 413) in which the household head was under 45.

  7. In 2004, the questionnaire did not include any information on education and occupation of children living with their parents. This explains the smaller number of observations for the 2004 survey.

  8. However, there is no information on the amounts received by children.

  9. Among workers, the male-female ratio was 2.5 for cohorts born before 1945, 4 for cohorts born before 1955 and 1959, 6 for cohorts born between 1975 and 1979, and even 8 for cohorts born since 1980.

  10. Regional dummies and dummies for size of urban unit, which are expected to explain differences in educational supply, will also be taken into account.

  11. However, compared to two-child families, the proportion of having high education is lower for one-child families (42.3 % compared to 45.6 %).

  12. For families with four or five children, the proportion of children with more than high school education appears to be U-shaped with respect to birth order in the USA (Hanushek 1992). Kantarevic and Mechoulan (2006) analyze this puzzling stylized fact and find that it stems from the confounding factor of the mother’s age at birth. That is, when age of the mother at birth is controlled for, the inverse U-shape relationship disappears.

  13. This includes for instance the degree of parental altruism which should be positively correlated with investment in the human capital of children (Becker and Tomes 1986).

  14. We set μ 0 = − and μ K  = + and assume that the thresholds are strictly ordered (μ k−1 < μ k ).

  15. For co-resident children, the 1992 Wealth survey indicates whether they have completed the undergraduate level or the graduate/postgraduate level.

  16. We have also estimated ordered regressions using the birth order index proposed by Booth and Kee (2009). These additional results, which are available upon request, lead to similar conclusions.

  17. In our regressions, we control for the head’s age at birth since we do not always have information on both spouses for each child. Recall that the parent sample is constructed by assembling information on the head’s characteristics and spousal characteristics, if any.

  18. We have also considered a piecewise linear function for the child’s age, by adding both age and birth cohort dummies interacted by age in the regression.

  19. We have also estimated the random effect ordered Probit regression on the subsample of families whose youngest child is at least 24. The corresponding estimates are very close to those reported in column 1 of Table 3, with a negative and significant correlation between birth order and education.

  20. By definition, parental characteristics which remain constant at the sibship level are picked up by the family fixed effect and are thus excluded from the regression.

  21. We thank an anonymous referee for this insight.

  22. We also estimated our regressions on the subsample of families where all siblings are employed and reach similar conclusions concerning the role of birth order. We also investigated the relationship between unemployment and family characteristics, with a focus on non-co-resident children interviewed either in 1998, 2004, or 2010 given data constraints. When estimate a random effect Probit model to explain the probability for a child to be unemployed, we find no significant relationship between the probability of being unemployed and birth order.

  23. For three children and higher families, results from Wald tests show that the birth order coefficients are not jointly significant.

  24. At first sight, it could be a little surprising that the random and fixed effect estimates differ since there should be no correlation between birth order and family-level unobservables conditional on family size. However, both regressions are not estimated on the same sample of children. The fixed effect ordered models rely on the estimate of conditional Logit models, so that sibships in which children all have the same occupation are excluded.

  25. Specifically, these authors find that first borns get more education but also argue that by age 30, no birth rank effect persists across siblings. They explain their findings by claiming that later borns are more risk taking than first borns. It remains to be explained why later borns would not outpace first borns after age 30, however.

  26. Hence, the difference in transfer income derivatives has to be equal to minus one, a property called redistributive neutrality (see Laferrère and Wolff 2006).

  27. Alternative explanations have been suggested to explain equal sharing within the family. For instance, parents may suffer from a psychic cost when deviating from an equal allocation of resources (Wilhelm 1996).

  28. In the French Wealth surveys, there is no information on the amount per transfer for regular or irregular cash gifts.

  29. Assuming that the probability of a child to be in financial problems is p, then the probability of transferring to all children is p n for a family with n children. The probability of an uneven distribution is 1 − p n − (1 − p)n, which is an increasing function of n.

  30. Children aged between 30 and 39 are more likely to receive a gift from their parents, while the other characteristics have no significant influence (presumably due to small sample size).

  31. These additional results are available upon request. In the fixed effect linear regression, both gender and education of the child have no significant influence on receiving money from parents.

  32. A few papers have investigated the existence of interactions between siblings in long-term care decisions (Heidemann and Stern 1999; Engers and Stern 2002; Byrne et al. 2009; Fontaine et al. 2009).

  33. Data limitations do not allow us to go further. In particular, we would like to know the amounts at stake to quantify the transfer differentials and compare those to other siblings’ outcome differentials. While we can only observe the presence of financial transfers, we are not able to compare amounts as well as other forms of cash gifts across siblings.

  34. At the same time, there may be strategic considerations within the sibship to avoid the burden of providing care to parents. See in particular Konrad et al. (2002) and Stern (2014).

References

  • Altonji JG, Hayashi F, Kotlikoff LJ (1997) Parental altruism and inter vivos transfers: theory and evidence. J Polit Econ 105:1121–1166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1991) A treatise on the family. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS, Lewis HG (1973) On the interaction between the quantity and quality of children. J Polit Econ 81:S279–S288

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS, Tomes N (1986) Human capital and the rise and fall of families. J Labor Econ 4:S1–S39

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertoni M, Brunello G (2013) Laterborns don’t give up. The effects of birth order on earnings in Europe. IZA DP No. 7679

  • Black SE, Devereux PJ, Salvanes KG (2005) The more the merrier? The effect of family size and birth order on children’s education. Q J Econ 120:669–700

    Google Scholar 

  • Black SE, Devereux PJ, Salvanes KG (2011) Older and wiser? Birth order and IQ of young men. CESifo Econ Stud 57:103–120

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Booth AL, Kee HJ (2009) Birth order matters: the effect of family size and birth order on educational attainment. J Popul Econ 22:367–397

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Butler LS, Moffitt R (1982) A computationally efficient quadrature procedure for the one factor multinomial Probit model. Econometrica 50:761–764

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Byrne D, Goeree M, Hiedemann B, Stern S (2009) Formal home health care, informal care, and family decision-making. Int Econ Rev 50:1205–1242

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chamberlain G (1980) Analysis of covariance with qualitative data. Rev Econ Stud 47:225–238

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cigno A (1991) Economics of the family. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Cigno A (1993) Intergenerational transfers without altruism: family, market and state. Eur J Polit Econ 9:505–518

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox D (1987) Motives for private income transfers. J Polit Econ 95:508–546

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox D (1990) Intergenerational transfers and liquidity constraints. Q J Econ 104:187–218

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox D, Rank MR (1992) Inter vivos transfers and intergenerational exchange. Rev Econ Stat 74:305–314

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Das M, van Soest A (1999) A panel data model for subjective information on household income growth. J Econ Behav Organ 40:409–426

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Haan M (2010) Birth order, family size and educational attainment. Econ Educ Rev 29:576–588

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Haan M, Plug E, Rosero J (2014) Birth order and human capital development: evidence from Ecuador. J Hum Resour 49:359–392

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Downey DB (2001) Number of siblings and intellectual development. The resource dilution explanation. Am Psychol 56:497–504

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edmonds E (2006) Understanding sibling differences in child labor. J Popul Econ 19:795–821

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ejrnaes M, Pörtner C (2004) Birth order and the intra-household allocation of time and education. Rev Econ Stat 86:1008–1019

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Emerson P, Souza AP (2008) Birth order, child labor, and school attendance in Brazil. World Dev 36:1647–1664

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engers M, Stern S (2002) Long-term care and family bargaining. Int Econ Rev 43:73–114

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fontaine F, Gramain A, Wittwer J (2009) Providing care for an elderly parent: interactions among siblings? Health Econ 18:1011–1029

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frechette GR (2001) Random effects ordered Probit. Stata Tech Bull 159:23–27

    Google Scholar 

  • Greene WH, Hensher DA (2010) Modeling ordered choices. A primer. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hanushek EA (1992) The trade-off between child quantity and quality. J Polit Econ 100:84–117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heidemann B, Stern S (1999) Strategic play among family members when making long-term care decisions. J Econ Behav Organ 40:29–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hotz V, Pantano J (2015) Strategic parenting, birth order and school performance. J. Popul. Econ. doi: 10.1007/s00148-015-0542-3

  • Jellal M, Wolff FC (2002) Aides aux parents âgés et allocation intra-familiale. Rev Econ 53:863–885

    Google Scholar 

  • Kantarevic J, Mechoulan S (2006) Birth order, educational attainment, and earnings. An investigation using the PSID. J Hum Resour 41:756–776

    Google Scholar 

  • Konrad K, Künemund H, Lommerud K, Robledo J (2002) Geography of the family. Am Econ Rev 92:981–998

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kureishi W, Wakabayashi M (2010) Why do first-born children live together with parents? Jpn World Econ 22:159–172

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laferrère A, Wolff FC (2006) Microeconomic models of family transfers. In: Kolm SC, Mercier Ythier J (eds) Handbook on the economics of giving, altruism and reciprocity, vol 2. Elsevier, North-Holland, pp 889–969

    Google Scholar 

  • Lehmann JY, Nuevo-Chiquero A, Vidal-Fernandez M (2014) The early origins of birth order differences in children’s outcomes and parental behavior, mimeo. University of New South, Wales

    Google Scholar 

  • Maurin E, McNally S (2008) Vive la Révolution ! Long term returns of 1968 to the angry students. J Labor Econ 26:1–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Price J (2008) Parent-child quality time: does birth order matter? J Hum Resour 43:240–265

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stern S (2014) O brother, where art thou? We need your help. Mimeo, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilhelm MO (1996) Bequest behavior and their effect of heir’s earnings: testing the altruistic model of bequests. Am Econ Rev 86:874–892

    Google Scholar 

  • Wolff FC (2000) Transferts monétaires inter vivos et cycle de vie. Rev Écon 51:1419–1452

    Google Scholar 

  • Zajonc RB (1976) Family configuration and intelligence: variations in scholastic aptitude scores parallel trends in family size and the spacing of children. Science 192:227–236

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgment

We are indebted to two anonymous reviewers for their very helpful comments and suggestions on previous versions of this paper. We also thank Hippolyte d’Albis, Carole Bonnet, Laurent Gobillon, Robert Pollak, Anne Solaz, and seminar participants at the Paris Seminar in Economic Demography, McMaster University, the University of Guelph, Ryerson University, and L’Université du Québec in Montréal. Any remaining errors are ours.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to François-Charles Wolff.

Additional information

Responsible Editor: Responsible Editor: Junsen Zhang

Appendix

Appendix

Table 7 Ordered Probit estimates for education and occupation, by family size

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Mechoulan, S., Wolff, FC. Intra-household allocation of family resources and birth order: evidence from France using siblings data. J Popul Econ 28, 937–964 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-015-0556-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-015-0556-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation