Skip to main content
Log in

Durable consumption, saving and retirement

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Durables yield services through life but are also a store of value and both features may have important implications for savings and retirement decisions. Durables also affect bequests and thus induce intergenerational transfers. We show that allowing explicitly for durables has important implications for retirement decisions and responses to various changes in the environment. An improvement in the possibility of freeing housing capital makes the old retire earlier (income effect) while the young plan to retire later since they increase housing demand and reduce financial savings. Considering welfare in stationary equilibrium, we find that a reduction in wealth locking-in in durables is not necessarily welfare improving due to the effects on bequests. From a social welfare perspective, individuals tend to choose too much financial savings, too little durable acquisition and too early retirement.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The relationship between housing wealth and retirement has been considered by Doling and Horsewood (2003) using aggregate data for 19 countries (mostly EU member states) for the period 1990–1996. They find that the labour force participation rate for men aged 55–64 depends negatively on the home ownership rate. See also Farnham and Sevak (2007) and Blake (2004).

  2. Feinstein and McFadden (1989) and Venti and Wise (2002, 2004) find that the elderly in the USA do not, or only very slowly, decumulate housing equity. Significant reductions are mostly associated with the death of a spouse or deteriorating health. Yang (2009) shows that the lifecycle profile for housing stock is monotonically increasing in young ages and almost flat in old age. In a recent study, Chiuri and Jappelli (2010) estimate ownership trajectories for 15 OECD countries and they find small changes in ownership rates up to the age 65–70, but more substantial changes with considerable dispersion between countries for higher ages.

  3. A reverse mortgage allows the homeowner to receive part of the equity value in various ways (lump-sum payment, annuity, line of credit etc.), and all interest and repayment is made when the owner dies or voluntarily sells the house.

  4. Karatzas and Wang (2000) provide the mathematical tools for determining the optimal retirement time in the consumption-portfolio choice framework.

  5. Price variations introduce both risk and speculation. Moreover, price dynamics may arise due to changes in the demographic composition of the population, see e.g. Ċerný et al. (2010).

  6. That is, the survival probability to given ages may change, and thus longevity measured either by life expectancy at birth or longest achievable age may change, see Andersen and Gestsson (2010).

  7. For simplicity, we do not model the habit formation explicitly but impose the same choice of the durable good in young and old age. Habit formation could be implemented by specifying old age utility from durable consumption in deviation from the level chosen in young age. Infinite punishment for deviation from the amount of durable chosen in young age would then correspond to complete habit formation.

  8. It is assumed that the house does not depreciate, but this can easily be relaxed without changing the qualitative results by assuming that only a fraction of the house acquired as young is left when old.

  9. We could denote, \(f ph\), ‘consumable housing wealth’, cf. above.

  10. OECD (2006) also applies a healthy ageing assumption in projections of health and long-term care expenditures.

  11. Diamond (2003) assumes that disutility of work is a non-increasing function of the survival probability.

  12. To ensure that there is always some retirement period, we assume \( \lim _{R\rightarrow L}d'\left (\frac {R}{L}\right )=\infty \).

  13. Assuming an explicit bequest motive would make locking-in of wealth less costly for the representative agent. To change our results, however, the bequest motive has to be so strong that the desired amount of bequest exceeds the amount of wealth locked-in in the durable good as old.

  14. Assuming an interior solution for h.

  15. This is in line with the results of the deregulation of financial markets in the late 1970s and 1980s. The personal savings ratio dropped since households chose to spend some of their housing equity (Blake 2004).

  16. From Eq. 13 it can be shown that at least one of \(s^{\ast }\) and \(h^{\ast }\) has to be increasing in longevity.

  17. Note that the decisions made by the young are time consistent, and hence this situation arises only if unanticipated news arise. If the change in e.g. longevity is unanticipated but permanent, there will only be a difference between the planned and actual retirement for the generation for whom the shock is unanticipated.

  18. In the decentralized solution, the agent chooses a lower h than what is socially optimal. Therefore, an increase in f can only be welfare improving if it induces the agent to raise h sufficiently. In other words, bequests are not internalized, and they are too low socially. Raising f worsens the latter, but might help to reduce the negative consequences of the former, and therefore, the effect is ambiguous in the decentralized equilibrium.

References

  • Andersen TM (2008) Increasing longevity and social security reforms—a legislative procedure approach. J Public Econ 92(3–4):633–646

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andersen TM, Bhattacharya J (2013) A dynamic efficiency rationale for public investment in the health of the young. Can J Econ (In press)

  • Andersen TM, Gestsson MH (2010) Longevity, growth and intergenerational equity—the deterministic case, economics working paper 2010-19, Aarhus University

  • Batljan I, Lagergren M (2004) Inpatient/outpatient health care costs and remaining years of life—effect of decreasing mortality on future acute health care demand. Soc Sci Med 59(12):2459–2466

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blake D (2004) The impact of wealth on consumption and retirement behaviour in the UK. Appl Finan Econ 14(8):555–576

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard O, Fischer S (1989) Lectures on macroeconomics. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Bloom DE, Canning D, Mansfield RK, Moore M (2007) Demographic change, social security systems, and savings. J Monetary Econ 54(1):92–114

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bodie Z, Merton RC, Samuelson WF (1992) Labor supply flexibility and portfolio choice in a life cycle model. J Econ Dyn Control 16(3–4):427–449

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bucks BK, Kennickell AB, Mach TL, Moore KB (2009) Changes in U.S. family finances from 2004 to 2007: evidence from the survey of consumer finances. Fed Reserve Bull 95:A1–A55

    Google Scholar 

  • Ċerný A, Miles D, Schmidt L (2010) The impact of changing demographics and pensions on the demand for housing and financial assets. J Pension Econ Finan 9(3):393–420

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang FR (1991) Uncertain lifetimes, retirement and economic welfare. Economica 58(230):215–232

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiuri M, Jappelli T (2010) Do the elderly reduce housing equity? an international comparison. J Popul Econ 23:643–663

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cocco JF (2005) Portfolio choice in the presence of housing. Rev Finan Stud 18(2):535–567

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crawford V, Lilien D (1981) Social security and the retirement decision. Q J Econ 96(3):505–529

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond PA (2003) Taxation, incomplete markets and social security: the 2000 munich lectures. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Doling J, Horsewood N (2003) Home ownership and early retirement: european experience in the 1990s. J Hous Built Environ 18:289–308

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farnham M, Sevak P (2007) Housing wealth and retirement timing, working paper 2007–172, Michigan retirement research center

  • Feinstein J, McFadden D (1989) The dynamics of housing demand by the elderly: wealth, cash flow, and demographic effects. In: Wise DA (ed) The economics of aging. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 55–92

  • Fries JF, Bruce B, Chakravarty E (2011) Compression of morbidity 1980–2011: a focused review of paradigms and progress. J Aging Res Article ID 261702

  • Hu SC (1979) Social security, the supply of labor, and capital accumulation. Am Econ Rev 69(3):274–83

    Google Scholar 

  • Karatzas I, Wang H (2000) Utility maximization with discretionary stopping. SIAM J Control Optim 39(1):306–329

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kraft H, Munk C (2011) Optimal housing, consumption, and investment decision over the life cycle. Manage Sci 57:1025–1041

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton RC (1969) Lifetime portfolio selection under uncertainty: the continuous-time case. Rev Econ Stat 51(3):247–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2006) Projecting OECD health and long-term care expenditures: what are the main drivers?, economics department working papers 477

  • Payne G, Laporte A, Deber R, Coyte PC (2007) Counting backward to health care’s future: using time-to-death modeling to identify changes in end-of-life morbidity and the impact of aging on health care expenditures. Milbank Q 85(2):213–257

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pecchenino RA, Pollard PS (1997) The effects of annuities, bequests, and aging in an overlapping generations model of endogenous growth. Econ J 107(440):26–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pestieau P, Ponthière G (2012) The public economics of increasing longevity. Hacienda Pública Española/Rev Public Econ 200(1):41–74

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer PM (1986) Increasing returns and long-run growth. J Polit Econ 94(5):1002–1037

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Venti SF, Wise DA (2002) Aging and housing equity. In: Mitchell OS, Bodie Z, Hammond PB, Zeldes S (eds) Innovations in retirement financing. University of Pennsylvania Press, Philadelphia, pp 254–281

    Google Scholar 

  • Venti SF, Wise DA (2004) Aging and housing equity: another look. In: Wise DA (ed) Perspectives on the economics of aging. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 127–175

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Werblow A, Felder S, Zweifel P (2007) Population ageing and health care expenditure: a school of ‘red herrings’Health Econ 16(10):1109–1126

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang F (2009) Consumption over the life cycle: how different is housing. Rev Econ Dyn 12(3):423–443

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zweifel P, Felder S, Meiers M (1999) Ageing of population and health care expenditure: a red herringHealth Econ 8(6):485–496

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We gratefully acknowledge comments from two anonymous referees, Christian Bjørnskov, Svend E. Hougaard Jensen, Valdemar Smith and Øystein Thøgersen.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mikkel Nørlem Hermansen.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Alessandro Cigno

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

(PDF 1.05 MB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Andersen, T.M., Hermansen, M.N. Durable consumption, saving and retirement. J Popul Econ 27, 825–840 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-013-0490-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-013-0490-8

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation