Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Gender-specific labor market conditions and family formation

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Slack labor market conditions for women relative to men increase the marriage rate in the USA. This paper examines the long-term consequences of such marriages. Despite the significant effect on marriage timing, labor market conditions experienced in youth do not affect the probability that a woman will marry by the age of 30. Further, labor market conditions at the time of marriage are uncorrelated with the probability of divorce, spouses’ characteristics, or the number of children. These findings suggest that labor market fluctuations induce only intertemporal adjustments for marriage timing without affecting reservation match quality or total fertility.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. An important presumption of these studies is that women can shift labor supply intertemporary so that they can marry and bear children when the opportunity costs are low. In countries with more rigid labor market structures than the USA, it may be more difficult for women to find a job after child-bearing, and thus, there may be less room for intertemporal substitution between market work and family activities. Indeed, Gutiérrez-Domènech (2008) finds that a high unemployment rate delays marriage and fertility of Spanish women because potential mothers care not only of their current employment status but also in their expected possibilities to work afterward.

  2. Among the studies conducted on fertility, the study of Dehejia and Lleras-Muney (2004), who investigate the relationship between the unemployment rate at the time of conception and the baby’s health outcome in the long run, has similarities with this paper in terms of empirical specification.

  3. Another response that a woman could do when she faced bad labor market condition in her state is to move to another state where labor market conditions are better, and indeed, young people move away from states with high unemployment (Wozniak 2010). Although such moves may have weaken the actual effects of contemporaneous labor market conditions on marriage formation, empirically, there remains statistically significant effect. Also, endogenous mobility does not bias the estimates of the effect of labor market conditions experienced at the age of 18–20 in the state of birth, which is the main explanation variable of this paper because the state of birth is predetermined.

  4. As a robustness check, I confirmed that replacing unemployment rates experienced between the ages of 18 and 20 with those between ages of 19 and 21 does not qualitatively change the results of any analyses in this paper. The ESM—Appendix also shows the results obtained using unemployment rates experienced between the ages of 22 and 24 for a subsample of 4-year college graduates. The basic results hold for this group, except that the average timing of marriage is about 3 years later than that of the rest of the sample.

  5. I used linear OLS with the cohort-level data because it makes the comparison between the coefficients for the different ages easier than probit or logit. As a robustness check, ESM—Appendix shows that probit regressions which use the actual state of residence at age 18–20 for high school graduates and at age 22–24 for college graduates yield the marginal effects of unemployment rates of the similar size and statistical significance.

  6. In the ESM—Appendix, I also report the results with controls for college education, which are qualitatively the same, even though the decision to acquire college education could be affected by the decision to marry. Such reverse causality from marriage to education might exist for the case of high school completion if high school students are forward looking and take in to account the prospect in the marriage market, but at least such decision is not affected by the unemployment rate at age 18–20.

  7. I restrict my sample to women because fertility history is available only for women. Note that, since the SIPP is a household survey, most of the married men in the data are the spouses of women in the same data. Therefore, the results on marriage formation and dissolution are expected to be identical, except that the men are slightly older than the women, and I confirm that the results are actually very similar.

  8. I do not retrieve data prior to 1978 because unemployment rates by gender are not available at the state level prior to 1978.

  9. Another important drawback of the SIPP is the incomplete migration history. This issue is described in detail in the ESM—Appendix.

  10. Another solution is to use a real panel dataset. In an earlier version circulated as Columbia PER Discussion Paper 0809-08, I also used the PSID for supplemental analyses. I confirmed that the results are qualitatively identical.

  11. Another important difference is that panels prior to 1996 are overlapping. Until 1993, a new panel had been introduced every year. Later, these were replaced by the 1996 redesign that used larger, non-overlapping panels. Nevertheless, results from 1990 to 1993 panels are similar to those estimated using the 1996–2004 panels. Therefore, I believe that the change in the sampling scheme does not render any bias to this paper.

  12. I have tried to do the same exercise with African-American women in the SIPP. However, the estimated coefficients of the unemployment rates have much larger standard errors, probably because of the smaller sample size and prevailed unmarried cohabitation. Also African-American population is concentrated to several large states such as New York, which might have made it difficult to identify the effect of unemployment rates net of state fixed effects. For Hispanics, in addition to the uneven distribution of the current residence, non-negligible fraction of the sample were born outside of the USA and thus cannot be assigned the unemployment rate at age 18–20.

  13. Maine and Vermont are grouped together, and North Dakota, South Dakota, and Wyoming are grouped together because the original variable for the state of current residence in the SIPP is defined in such a way. Alaska, Washington DC, and Hawaii are dropped.

  14. There are about total 2,200,000 marriages per year (NCHS 2008), 90% of which involve women younger than 45 (US Census Bureau 2005). The population of 18–39 years old women is about 50,000,000 (US Census Bureau 2000).

  15. The state–year level gender-specific unemployment rates are not issued by the BLS but calculated from the micro-data by myself, so there is no official documentation about their sampling errors. However, according to BLS publication “Employment and Earnings (http://www.bls.gov/opub/ee/home.htm),” the sampling errors of the unemployment rate of white labor force in the entire USA are about 0.1%. Roughly speaking, the sampling errors of each state’s gender-specific unemployment rates should be approximately 0.1% times (the state’s population share in the US)^0.5. The population-weighted average of this value is about 8; thus, the sampling error is probably around 0.8%. Admittedly, 0.8% is very close to the size of remaining variations after controlling for the other gender’s unemployment rate, year dummies, and state dummies. Therefore, the estimated coefficients might be subject to attenuation bias from the measurement errors.

  16. I tried switching between linear OLS and probit for binary dependent variables and the results were robust. See ESM—Appendix Section B1 for some of the robustness checks.

  17. Robustness checks using the probit model are presented in the ESM—Appendix.

  18. Dropping the previous year’s unemployment rates do not change the coefficient of unemployment rates experienced between the ages of 18 and 20 much.

  19. One of the most recent follow-up studies is the one carried out by Lehrer (2008), which shows that the relationship between the age one marries and marital instability is strongly negative up to one’s late twenties.

  20. Card and Lemieux (2000) show that the unemployment rate at age 18 has a slightly negative effect on the years of schooling. In contrast, Kondo (2007) shows that the effects of a recession at the time of entry into the labor market on wages and employment are negligible for non-Hispanic white women, despite persistent, significantly negative effects for men. Hershbein (2010) also show that women who graduate during a period of high unemployment reduce their labor supply in the short run but long-term impacts on labor supply is minimal.

  21. It is true that a recession at graduation lowers earnings of male college graduates by about 1% for ten or more years after graduation (Kahn 2010; Genda et al. 2010). However, such effect is limited to male college graduates. The effects of a recession at entry on subsequent employment and earnings are temporary for male high school graduates (Genda et al. 2010) and even weaker and less persistent for women (Kondo 2007; Hershbein 2010).

  22. The author’s tabulation from SIPP 2004

References

  • Becker GS (1973) A theory of marriage: part I. J Polit Econ 81(4):813–846

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS, Landes EM, Michael RT (1977) An economic analysis of marital instability. J Polit Econ 85(6):1141–1187

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blackburn ML, Bloom DE, Neumark D (1993) Fertility timing, wages, and human capital. J Popul Econ 6(1):1–30

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blau FD, Kahn LM, Waldfogel J (2000) Understanding young women’s marriage decisions: the role of labor and marriage market conditions. Ind Labor Relat Rev 53(4):624–647

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bumpass LL, Sweet JA, Cherlin A (1991) The role of cohabitation in declining rates of marriage. J Marriage Fam 53(4):913–927

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Butz WP, Ward MP (1979) The emergence of countercyclical U. Am Econ Rev 69(3):318–328

    Google Scholar 

  • Card D, Lemieux T (2000) Dropout and enrollment trends in the post-war period: what went wrong in the 1970s? NBER working paper no. 7658, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA

  • Charles K, Stephens M (2004) Job displacement, disability, and divorce. J Labor Econ 22(2):489–522

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cherlin AJ (1992) Marriage, divorce, remarriage (revised and enlarged edition). Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Dehejia R, Lleras-Muney A (2004) Booms, busts, and babies’ health. Q J Econ 119(3):1091–1130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freiden A (1974) The United States marriage market. J Polit Econ 82(2):34–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Genda Y, Kondo A, Ohta S (2010) Long-term effects of a recession at labor market entry in Japan and the United States. J Hum Resour 45(1):157–196

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gould ED, Paserman MD (2003) Waiting for Mr. Right: rising inequality and declining marriage rates. J Urban Econ 53(2):257–281

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gutiérrez-Domènech M (2008) The impact of the labour market on the timing of marriage and births in Spain. J Popul Econ 21(1):83–110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hershbein B (2010) Graduating in a recession: the case of high school women. Mimeo, University of Michigan

  • Kahn LB (2010) The long-term labor market consequences of graduating from college in a bad economy. Labour Econ 17(2):303–316

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kondo A (2007) Differential effects of graduating during a recession across race and gender. ISERP working paper 07-05. Institute for Social and Economic Research and Policy, Columbia University, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Lehrer EL (2008) Age at marriage and marital instability: revisiting the Becker–Landes–Michael hypothesis. J Popul Econ 21(2):463–484

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loughran DS (2002) The effect of male wage inequality on female age at first marriage. Rev Econ Stat 84(2):237–250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manning WD, Smock PJ (1995) Why marry? Race and the transition to marriage among cohabitors. Demography 32(4):509–520

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller AR (2011) The effects of motherhood timing on career path. J Popul Econ (forthcoming)

  • NCHS (2008) National Vital Statistics System. Data available at http://www.cdc.gov/nchs/mardiv.htm

  • Preston SH, Richards AT (1975) The influence of women’s work opportunities on marriage rates. Demography 12(2):209–222

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schultz TP (1994) Marital status and fertility in the United States: welfare and labor market effects. J Hum Resour 29(2):637–669

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stevenson B, Wolfers J (2007) Marriage and divorce: changes and their driving forces. J Econ Perspect 21(2):27–52

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taniguchi H (1999) The timing of childbearing and women’s wages. J Marriage Fam 61(4):1008–1019

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • US Census Bureau (2000) Census 2000. Data available at http://www.census.gov/

  • US Census Bureau (2005) Number, timing, and duration of marriages and divorces: 2001. http://www.census.gov/prod/2005pubs/p70-97.pdf

  • Weiss Y, Wills RJ (1997) Match quality, new information and marital dissolution. J Labor Econ 15(1):293–329

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wood RG (1995) Marriage rates and marriageable men: a test of the Wilson hypothesis. J Hum Resour 30(1):163–193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wozniak A (2010) Are college graduates more responsive to distant labor market opportunities? J Hum Resour 45(4):944–970

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • White LK (1981) A note on racial differences in the effect of female economic opportunity on marriage rates. Demography 18(3):349–354

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This paper is a substantially revised version of “Female Labor Market Conditions and Family Formation,” Columbia PER Discussion Paper 0809-08. I am particularly indebted to my advisors, Janet Currie, Till von Wachter, and Bentley MacLeod, for their guidance and support. I also wish to thank Shubha Chakravarty, Pierre-André Chiappori, Lena Edlund, Joshua Goodman, Mariesa Herrmann, Fung-Mey Huang, Tümer Kapan, Dongshu Ou, Johannes Schmieder, Herdis Steingrimsdottir, Matthew Wai-Poi, Jane Waldfogel, and the editor and two anonymous referees of this journal for their helpful suggestions. I benefited from comments by the participants at student colloquia in Columbia, ZEW summer workshop, Asian conference 2009 on Applied Micro-Economics/Econometrics, seminars at the Institute for Statistical Research, Hitotsubashi University, Tohoku University, KISER Labor Workshop, Nihon University, and Kyoto University.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ayako Kondo.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Erdal Tekin

Electronic Supplementary Material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

(PDF 292 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Kondo, A. Gender-specific labor market conditions and family formation. J Popul Econ 25, 151–174 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-011-0367-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-011-0367-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation