Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Labor market competitiveness and the size of the informal sector

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper formalizes the dynamics of the informal sector with a special emphasis on the levels of labor market competitiveness in the formal and informal sectors. Specifically, it analyzes the effects of improved productivity and higher entry costs into the formal sector on the size of the informal sector for different degrees of competitiveness in the labor markets. We show that when the informal labor market is competitive while the formal labor market is not, lower production technology in the formal sector or a higher entry cost reduces the size of the informal sector in the long run.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For recent surveys, see Schneider and Enste (2000, 2003) and Gerxhani (2004). For manufacturing firms in developing countries, see Tybout (2000).

  2. Kingdon and Knight (2004) suggest that entry barriers also exist in the informal sector in South Africa. In contrast, Amaral and Quintin (2006) propose a theoretical possibility that such phenomena occur even in a perfectly competitive labor market with no entry barriers so long as informal managers, facing limited financial access, substitute low-skilled labor for physical capital.

  3. For evidence on the imperfectness of labor markets see, e.g., Sullivan (1989), Card and Krueger (1995) and Manning (2003).

  4. See also Banerjee (1984) and Assaad (1993) for earlier work. Bhaskar and To (1999) report that transportation costs are substantial even in developed economies like the USA, where transport costs are between 6% and 9% of a full-time minimum wage worker’s gross income.

  5. As an anonymous referee correctly pointed out, one of the most relevant differences between Dessy and Pallage (2003) and our paper is that we consider the case in which entry fees collected from formal sector firms by the government are not used to finance the provision of public goods. Therefore, entry costs in our model include bribes paid by formal sector firms to corrupt public officials. Our theoretical predictions match the empirical evidence provided by Dreher et al. (2009) and Virta (2010).

  6. The productivity of formal firms is higher than that of informal firms due to, say, a higher capital-labor ratio.

  7. In developing countries, formal wages tend to be higher than informal wages. See, e.g., Pradhan and van Soest (1995) and Kingdon and Knight (2004).

  8. Investment in education tends to be inactive in developing countries despite its high returns (Psacharopoulos 1985, 1994). This implies that because of poorly functioning credit markets, only children born to relatively wealthy families are able to receive sufficient education.

  9. An individual that continues to work in the same sector is also randomly relocated on that circle in the second period.

  10. Kats (1995) establishes that the ‘equal distance’ location pattern is an equilibrium of the two-stage location-price game, where firms simultaneously choose locations in the first stage and prices in the second stage.

  11. Consider the net income of a worker located at distance x from firm i, and distance \(\left(\frac{1}{n_0}-x\right)\) from firm j. His net income is y F (x,w i ) = w i  − sx if he works for firm i, \(y_F\left(\frac{1}{n_0}-x,w_j\right) = w_j - s\left(\frac{1}{n_0}-x\right)\) if he works for firm j, and zero if he is unemployed. Therefore, he works for firm i if and only if \(y_F(x,w_i)\geq\max\left\{0, y_F\left(\frac{1}{n_0}-x,w_j\right)\right\}\), which can be rewritten as \(x\leq\hat{x} \equiv \min\left\{\frac{w_i}{s}, \frac{1}{2s}\left(\frac{s}{n_0} + w_i - w_j\right)\right\}\) as it appears in the text. Moreover, provided that w i  ≥ 0 as usual, condition \(|w_i - w_j| \leq \frac{s}{n_0}\) guarantees that distance \(\hat{x}\) is non-negative. In other words, a firm never employs workers located on the other side of its adjacent firms.

  12. We ignore old formal workers here. This does not affect the following analysis.

  13. Since there does not exist a rational expectation concerning competition between firms when \(n_0\in\left(s/b,\,3s/2b\right]\), symmetric equilibria do not exist in such cases. Put differently, if the firm sets a wage expecting, for example, that it does not need to compete for workers with the adjacent firms, it turns out that the firm in fact needs to compete with the adjacent firms in order to employ the intended amount of labor when \(n_0\in\left(s/b,\,3s/2b\right]\).

  14. In other words, we restrict attention to the values of the parameters \(\hat{y}\), C I , C F , a, b, r, s, n 0 and m 0 such that n t and m t , which are respectively given by Eqs. 4 and 5, satisfy n t  ≤ s/b and m t  > 3r/2a for all t ≥ 0, respectively, assuming that such sequences \(\{n_t\}_{t=0}^\infty\) and \(\{m_t\}_{t=0}^\infty\) exist. It follows from Eq. 1 that \(w_{F,t} = b/2 > \hat{y}\) and \(w_{I,t} = a - r/m_t > \hat{y}~(\Leftrightarrow m_t > \max\{3r/2a,r/(a-\hat{y})\})\) must be satisfied for all t ≥ 0.

  15. The opposite case, in which the formal sector is relatively competitive \(\left(n_t > \frac{3s}{2b}\right)\) and the informal sector is relatively less competitive \(\left(m_t \leq \frac{r}{a}\right)\), is analyzed in the Appendix.

  16. In other words, these young individuals are located within distance (w F, t − 1 − C F )/s from the closest firms.

  17. Since the expected income of formal workers is higher than the profit of an informal-firm owner (\(\bar{y}_{F,t} > \pi_{I,t}\)), young formal workers in period t − 1 who could set up an informal firm in period t will not choose to do so.

  18. It should be noted that (w F  = ) b/2 > C F by assumption.

  19. The number of firms in the informal sector is larger in the new steady state. To see this, plug the steady state values, m t  = m t − 1 = m, \(\hat{G}_{t-1}=\hat{G}\), and w I  = a − r/m, into Eq. 5, and obtain

    $$ m=\frac{2rG}{2G\left(a-C_I\right)-r}. $$

    Clearly, the steady-state number of firms in the informal sector rises with C I .

References

  • Amaral PS, Quintin E (2006) A competitive model of the informal sector. J Monet Econ 53(7):1541–1553

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Assaad R (1993) Formal and informal institutions in the labor market, with applications to the construction sector in Egypt. World Dev 21(6):925–939

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Auriol E, Warlters M (2005) Taxation base in developing countries. J Public Econ 89(4):625–646

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee B (1984) Information flow, expectations and job search: rural-to-urban migration process in India. J Dev Econ 15(1–3):239–257

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhaskar V, To T (1999) Minimum wages for Ronald McDonald monopsonies: a theory of monopsonistic competition. Econ J 109(455):190–203

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhaskar V, To T (2003) Oligopsony and the distribution of wages. Eur Econ Rev 47(2):371–399

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Card D, Krueger AB (1995) Myth and measurement: the new economics of the minimum wage. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Dessy S, Pallage S (2003) Taxes, inequality and the size of the informal sector. J Dev Econ 70(1):225–233

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dreher A, Kotsogiannis C, McCorriston S (2009) How do institutions affect corruption and the shadow economy? Int Tax Public Financ 16(6):773–796

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman E, Johnson S, Kaufmann D, Zoido-Lobaton P (2000) Dodging the grabbing hand: the determinants of unofficial activity in 69 countries. J Public Econ 76(3):459–493

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerxhani K (2004) The informal sector in developed and less developed countries: a literature survey. Public Choice 120(3–4):267–300

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kajisa K (2007) Personal networks and nonagricultural employment: the case of a farming village in the Philippines. Econ Dev Cult Change 55(4):669–707

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kats A (1995) More on Hotelling’s stability in competition. Int J Ind Organ 13(1):89–93

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kingdon GG, Knight J (2004) Unemployment in South Africa: the nature of the beast. World Dev 32(3):391–408

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loayza NV (1996) The economics of the informal sector: a simple model and some empirical evidence from Latin America. Carnegie-Rochester Conf Ser Public Policy 45:129–162

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luke N, Munshi K, Rosenzweig M (2004) Marriage, networks, and jobs in third world cities. J Eur Econ Assoc 2(2–3):437–446

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luke N, Munshi K (2006) New roles for marriage in urban Africa: kinship networks and the labor market in Kenya. Rev Econ Stat 88(2):264–282

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manning A (2003) Monopsony in motion. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Pradhan M, van Soest A (1995) Formal and informal sector employment in urban areas of Bolivia. Labour Econ 2(3):275–297

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Psacharopoulos G (1985) Returns to education: a further international update and implications. J Hum Resour 20(4):583–604

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Psacharopoulos G (1994) Returns to investment in education: a global update. World Dev 22(9):1325–1343

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rauch JE (1991) Modelling the informal sector formally. J Dev Econ 35(1):33–47

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schneider F, Enste DH (2000) Shadow economies: size, causes, and consequences. J Econ Lit 38(1):77–114

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schneider F, Enste DH (2003) The shadow economy: an international survey. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Sullivan D (1989) Monopsony power in the market for nurses. J Law Econ 32(2):S135–S178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tybout JR (2000) Manufacturing firms in developing countries: how well do they do, and why? J Econ Lit 38(1):11–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Virta H (2010) The linkage between corruption and shadow economy size: does geography matter? International Journal of Development Issues 9(1):4–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wahba J, Zenou Y (2005) Density, social networks and job search methods: theory and application to Egypt. J Dev Econ 78(2):443–473

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors wish to thank the responsible editor, Alessandro Cigno, and two anonymous referees for their very useful comments and suggestions. Thanks are also due to Yoko Asuyama and Paul Kandasamy for their helpful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hideaki Goto.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Alessandro Cigno

Appendix: The case in which formal firms compete for workers whereas informal firms do not

Appendix: The case in which formal firms compete for workers whereas informal firms do not

In this appendix, we consider the case in which n > 3s/2b and m ≤ r/a. In this case, the wage in the formal sector increases as the number of formal firms rises (w F  = b − s/n), while the wage in the informal sector is independent of the number of informal firms (w I  = a/2). From these wages and the steady-state conditions, we obtain

$$ \hat{G} = \frac{r}{a - 2C_I}. $$

Thus, the size of the informal sector in the steady state is expressed as

$$ P_I^* = \frac{2r}{a - 2C_I}, $$

where \(P_I^* > 0\) because w I  = a/2 > C I . From this expression, we can see that the steady-state size of the informal sector is increasing in the transaction cost in its labor market (r) and the setup cost of an informal firm (C I ), and is decreasing in the productivity in the informal sector (a).

Suppose that C I increases for example. In the short run, the number of firms decreases and unemployment increases in the informal sector. As a result, fewer young individuals receive education, and thus more individuals enter the informal labor market. Given the same number of formal firms, the population size of the informal sector increases while that of the formal sector declines. In the next period, the number of formal firms decreases and that of informal firms increases. Since the labor market in the formal sector is more competitive than that in the informal sector, the wage and employment in the formal sector is more responsive to changes in the number of firms than those in the informal sector. Hence, the net worker inflow into the informal labor market increases. Therefore, the informal sector expands as the setup cost of an informal firm rises. The effects on the size of the informal sector of changes in the production technology and transaction costs in the informal sector can be understood in a similar way.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Goto, H., Mano, Y. Labor market competitiveness and the size of the informal sector. J Popul Econ 25, 495–509 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-011-0360-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-011-0360-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation