Skip to main content
Log in

The institution of marriage

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The institution of marriage is both old and ubiquitous. Yet, little work has been done by economists on why this social institution exists and why throughout history it has been intimately linked to fertility. We explain the institution of marriage as a societal consensus on the need to curb cuckoldry for the purpose of paternity certainty and biparental investment in offspring. By raising the costs of mating to individuals, marriage reduces cheating in society, a source of mating market failure, and makes paternity more certain. Men, in consequence, invest more in their putative offspring, a fact that also benefits mothers.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For surveys of theories of marriage, see, for example, the chapter by Weiss (1997) in the Handbook of Population and Family Economics, the monograph by Becker (1991), or the book by Grossbard-Shechtman (2003).

  2. This lack of differentiation between formal and informal unions has characterized the economics literature on marriage from its very beginning. As noted by Gary Becker in the introduction of his seminal paper on the economics of marriage, for individuals “ ‘marriage’ simply means that they share the same household” (Becker 1973, p. 815).

  3. We are grateful to an anonymous referee for pointing us to this unpublished study, which was released after the first version of this paper.

  4. The ancient Greek philosopher Aristotle noted as early as 350 B.C.E. that one of the reasons why mothers seem to love their children more than fathers is the fact that they know better that the children are indeed their own (Nicomachean Ethics, Book 9, Chapter 7). General concern about cuckoldry has also found vivid expression in popular proverbs such as “mama’s baby, papa’s maybe”, the modern English equivalent to the ancient Roman dictum “mater certissima, pater semper incertus” (mother is certain, father always uncertain).

  5. A review of the literature on the trade-off between the quantity and quality of own offspring for the reproductive success of individuals, known as K-strategies and r-strategies in the biological literature, is provided in Hill and Kaplan (1999). See also Kaplan and Lancaster (2003).

  6. Consistent with these reproductive strategies, significant sex differences have been observed across cultures also in mate preference. Men more than women tend to value signals of reproductive capacity or fertility in potential mates, such as features of physical appearance that are associated with youth and health. Women, in contrast, appear to put greater emphasis on attributes like status or earnings capacity, i.e., cues to the ability of potential mates to support them and their offspring (see, for example, Buss 1989).

  7. For a thorough treatment of the importance of female infidelity and paternal uncertainty for human mating strategies, see the recent book by Shackelford and Platek (2006).

  8. The assumption that V is twice differentiable with respect to discrete K can be relaxed, as long as V is monotonously increasing and strictly concave in K.

  9. Note that the price mechanism allows us to determine s and s and, in consequence, the number of partners and the degree of paternal uncertainty endogenously. The study by Saint-Paul (2008), in contrast, assumes that mating is either costless, if one is single, or prohibitively expensive, if one is not (extrapair mating entails infinite costs).

  10. Taxation of but one sex is in fact ruled out by our market clearing condition (Eq. 11).

  11. In other words, equilibrium allocations of resources will differ from the social optimum. A detailed discussion of the social optimum and of the cooperative reproductive strategies required for its attainment can be obtained from the authors upon request.

  12. The continuous choice first-order necessary conditions are provided in the “Appendix”.

  13. Parental altruism toward offspring is a special case of concern for biological relatives (Hamilton 1964a, b).

  14. Note that our explanation of marriage as an institution cannot explain how marriage emerges but it explains why it emerges. This feature is shared with economic explanations for the usage of money as a means to reduce transaction costs. One way to think about the emergence of marriage would be that it has organically evolved. The interested reader is referred to the book by Schotter (2008) for a more detailed treatment of economic theories of social institutions.

  15. Traditional fault grounds include, among others, emotional or physical cruelty, adultery, and desertion.

  16. The Gamma function can be viewed as an extension of the factorial function for arbitrary numbers in ℂ, except zero and negative integers: Γ(n + 1) = n! for all n ∈ ℕ0. \(\Gamma(\frac{1}{2})=\sqrt{\pi}\) and \(\Gamma(\frac{3}{2})=\frac{1}{2}\sqrt{\pi}\) provide nice examples for values of the Gamma function evaluated at noninteger numbers.

References

  • Alexander RD (1974) The evolution of social behavior. Ann Rev Ecolog Syst 5:325–383

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alexander RD (1979) Darwinism and human affairs. University of Washington Press, Seattle

    Google Scholar 

  • Bateman AJ (1948) Intrasexual selection in Drosophila. Heredity 2(3):349–368

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1965) A theory of the allocation of time. Econ J 75(299):493–517

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1973) A theory of marriage: part I. J Polit Econ 81(4):813–846

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1974) A theory of marriage: part II. J Polit Econ 82(2):S11–S26

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1985) Human capital, effort, and the sexual division of labor. J Labor Econ 3(1):S33–S58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1991) A treatise on the family. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Blau FD, Kahn LM, Waldfogel J (2000) Understanding young women’s marriage decisions: the role of labor and marriage market conditions. Ind Labor Relat Rev 53(4):624–647

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bullough VL (1976) Sexual variance in society and history. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Buss DM (1989) Sex differences in human mate preferences: evolutionary hypotheses tested in 37 cultures. Behav Brain Sci 12(1):1–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buss DM (2002) Human mate guarding. Neuro-endocrinol Lett 23(4):23–29 (special issue)

    Google Scholar 

  • Case A, Lin I-F, McLanahan S (1999) Household resource allocation in stepfamilies: Darwin reflects on the plight of cinderella. In: American economic review—papers and proceedings of the 111th annual meeting of the American Economic Association, vol 89(2), pp 234–238

  • Cox D (1987) Motives for private income transfers. J Polit Econ 95(3):508–546

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox D (1990) Intergenerational transfers and liquidity constraints. Q J Econ 105(1):187–217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox D (2003) Private transfers within the family: mothers, fathers, sons and daughters. In: Munnell AH, Sundén A (eds) Death and dollars: the role of gifts and bequests in America. Brookings Institution, Washington, DC, pp 168–209

    Google Scholar 

  • Daly M, Wilson MI (1982) Whom are newborn babies said to resemble? Ethol Sociobiol 3:69–78

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daly M, Wilson MI (1985) Child abuse and other risks of not living with both parents. Ethol Sociobiol 6(4):197–210

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daly M, Wilson MI, Weghorst SJ (1982) Male sexual jealousy. Ethol Sociobiol 3(1):11–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Darwin C (1871) The decent of man, and selection in relation to sex. Murray, London

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Edlund L (2005) The role of paternity presumption and custodial rights for understanding marriage patterns. Mimeo, Columbia University

  • Edlund L, Korn E (2002) A theory of prostitution. J Polit Econ 110(1):181–214

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedberg L (1998) Did unilateral divorce raise divorce rates? Evidence from panel data. Am Econ Rev 88(3):608–627

    Google Scholar 

  • Gaulin SJC, Schlegel A (1980) Paternal confidence and paternal investment: a cross-cultural test of a sociobiological hypothesis. Ethol Sociobiol 1(4):301–309

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaulin SJC, McBurney DH, Brakeman-Wartell SL (1997) Matrilineal biases in the investment of aunts and uncles: a consequence and measure of paternity uncertainty. Human Nat 8:139–151

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene PJ (1978) Promiscuity, paternity, and culture. Am Ethnol 5(1):151–159

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossbard-Shechtman SA (2003) Marriage and the economy. In: Grossbard-Shechtman SA (ed) Marriage and the economy. Theory and evidence from advanced industrial countries. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 1–34

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Gruber J (2004) Is making divorce easier bad for children? The long run implications of unilateral divorce. J Labor Econ 22(4):799–833

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hadjiyannakis C (1969) Les tendances contemporaines concernant la répression du délit d’adultère. Association Internationale du Droit Pénal, Thessalonika

  • Hamilton WD (1964a) The genetical theory of social behaviour I. J Theor Biol 7(1):1–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton WD (1964b) The genetical theory of social behaviour II. J Theor Biol 7(1):17–52

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hartung J (1985) Matrilineal inheritance: new theory and analysis. Behav Brain Sci 8(4):661–688

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hess GD (2004) Marriage and consumption insurance: what’s love got to do with it? J Polit Econ 112(2):290–318

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hill K, Kaplan HS (1999) Life history traits in humans: theory and empirical studies. Annu Rev Anthropol 28:397–430

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoffmann-Jørgensen J (1994) Probability with a view towards statistics. Chapman & Hall, Boca Raton

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan HS, Lancaster JB (2003) An evolutionary and ecological analysis of human fertility, mating patterns, and parental investment. In: Wachter KW, Bulatao RA (eds) Offspring: human fertility behavior in biodemographic perspective. National Academies, Washington, DC, pp 170–223

    Google Scholar 

  • Kotlikoff LJ, Spivak A (1981) The family as an incomplete annuities market. J Polit Econ 89(2):372–391

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landes EM (1978) Economics of alimony. J Legal Stud 7(1):35–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lefebvre P, Merrigan P (1998) The impact of welfare benefits on the conjugal status of single mothers in Canada: estimates from a hazard model. J Hum Resour 33(3):742–757

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundberg S, Pollak RA (1993) Separate spheres bargaining and the marriage market. J Polit Econ 101(6):988–1010

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundberg S, Pollak RA (1994) Noncooperative bargaining models of marriage. In: American economic review—papers and proceedings of the 106th annual meeting of the American Economic Association, vol 84(2), pp 132–137

  • Murdock GP (1967) Ethnographic atlas. Pittsburgh University Press, Pittsburgh

    Google Scholar 

  • Platek SM, Burch RL, Panyavin IS, Wasserman BH, Gallup Jr GG (2002) Reactions to children’s faces: resemblance affects males more than females. Evol Hum Behav 23(3):159–166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Platek SM, Critton SR, Burch RL, Frederick DA, Myers TE, Gallup Jr GG (2003) How much paternal resemblance is enough? Sex differences in hypothetical investment decisions but not in the detection of resemblance. Evol Hum Behav 24(2):81–87

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pollak RA (1985) A transaction cost approach to families and households. J Econ Lit 23(2):581–608

    Google Scholar 

  • Pollak RA, Wachter ML (1975) The relevance of the household production function and its implications for the allocation of time. J Polit Econ 83(2):255–278

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rasul I (2004) The impact of divorce laws on marriage. Mimeo, University of Chicago

  • Rosenzweig MR (1999) Welfare, marital prospects, and nonmarital childbearing. In: Journal of Political Economy, vol 107(6). Part 2: symposium on the economic analysis of social behavior in honor of Gary S. Becker, pp S3–S32

  • Saint-Paul G (2008) Genes, legitimacy and hypergamy: another look at the economics of marriage. Institut d’Économie Industrielle (IDEI), Working paper no 509

  • Schotter A (2008) The economic theory of social institutions. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Shackelford TK, Platek SM (2006) Female infidelity and paternal uncertainty: evolutionary perspectives on male anti-cuckoldry tactics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Shackelford TK, Buss DM, Bennett K (2002) Forgiveness or breakup: sex differences in responses to a partner’s infidelity. Cogn Emot 16(2):299–307

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stacey PB (1982) Female promiscuity and male reproductive success in social birds and mammals. Am Nat 120(1):51–64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Symons D (1979) The evolution of human sexuality. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Trivers RL (1972) Parental investment and sexual selection. In: Campbell B (ed) Sexual selection and the descent of man 1871–1971. Aldine, Chicago, pp 136–179

    Google Scholar 

  • Volk A, Quinsey VL (2002) The influence of infant facial cues on adoption preferences. Human Nat 13(4):437–455

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weiss Y (1997) The formation and dissolution of families: why marry? Who marries whom? And what happens upon divorce? In: Rosenzweig MR, Stark O (eds) Handbook of population and family economics, vol 1A. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 81–123

    Google Scholar 

  • Weiss Y, Willis RJ (1985) Children as collective goods and divorce settlements. J Labor Econ 3(3):268–292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weiss Y, Willis RJ (1993) Transfers among divorced couples: evidence and interpretation. J Labor Econ 11(6):629–679

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Willis RJ (1999) A theory of out-of-wedlock childbearing. J Polit Econ 107(6):S33–S64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson MI, Daly M (1987) Risk of maltreatment of children living with stepparents. In: Gelles RJ, Lancaster JB (eds) Child abuse and neglect: biosocial dimensions. Aldine de Gruyter, Hawthorne, pp 215–232

    Google Scholar 

  • Wolfe SJ (1975) On moments of probability distribution functions. In: Ross B (ed) Fractional calculus and its applications—lecture notes in mathematics, vol 457. Springer, Berlin, pp 306–316

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

An earlier version of this paper circulated under the title “Paternal Uncertainty and the Economics of Mating, Marriage, and Parental Investment in Children” (SFB 649 Discussion Paper 46, Humboldt University of Berlin, 2005). Our work has benefited from useful comments by Michael C. Burda, Andrew McClelland, Irwin Collier, Donald Cox, Kurt Helmes, Jong-Wha Lee, Thomas Siedler, and Harald Uhlig. We are also grateful to two anonymous referees for their constructive comments. Stephanie Andrews, Burcu Erdogan, Katja Hanewald, and Redzo Mujcic have provided valuable research assistance. All remaining errors are our own. Financial support by the Fritz Thyssen Stiftung, the Brain Korea 21 Program, and the Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft through the SFB 649 “Economic Risk” is gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Dirk Bethmann.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Deborah Cobb-Clark

Appendix: Continuous choice

Appendix: Continuous choice

For expository and analytical reasons, we have changed to a continuous choice of mating partners in Section 5. Separable utility of women and men is isoelastic in nonreproductive consumption and Cobb–Douglas in the quantity and quality of own offspring (Eq. 19). Hence, the optimization problem of females is given by:

(20)

This change implies the following first-order necessary conditions for the representative female. Her optimal investment in child quality Q Female has to meet the condition:

(21)

and her optimal continuous choice of male mating partners N has to satisfy:

(22)

A man’s expected utility from reproduction is determined by the same expression in child quality as in the female case times the (fractional) ν-th moment of the binomial distribution with N draws (female partners) and probability of success (fatherhood) δ:

(23)

According to Hoffmann-Jørgensen (1994, p. 303), the fractional moment of a nonnegative random variable can be calculated using the following formular:

(24)

where Γ is Euler’s Gamma functionFootnote 16 and M (τ) denotes the respective moment generating function with the property that the n-th moment about the origin is given by the n-th derivative evaluated at zero. The formular (24) can be obtained by using techniques of fractional calculus and taking the derivative of the \(\nu^{\text{th}}\) order of M(τ) (for details see Wolfe 1975). For our purposes, it is important to note that K is indeed a nonnegative random variable and that the moment generating function of the underlying binomial distribution is given by:

(25)

Substituting the moment generating function (25) into formular (24) and applying the rule of integration by substitution with \(z=t^{\frac{1}{\nu}}\) leads to the following result:

(26)

We can now address the man’s continuous choice optimization problem. Treating the probability of biological fatherhood δ as exogenously given, a male individual chooses q and N to maximize his expected utility:

(27)

This leads us to the following first-order necessary condition with respect to q :

(28)

The first-order necessary condition with respect to N , in turn, is as follows:

(29)

Note that given the probability of fatherhood δ, a man’s expected utility with respect to the number of own offspring, i.e., the fractional moment determined by Eq. 26, is increasing at a diminishing rate in the number of female partners N :

(30)

In other words, the fractional moment is concave in N .

The solution to the model is described by the first-order necessary conditions (Eqs. 21 and 22) for females, their counterparts for males (Eq. 28 and 29), the mating market clearing condition (Eq. 11), and the mating cost constraint (Eq. 12). We used the Mathematica function “FindRoot” to solve this system of equations for the optimal values of Q , N , q , N , s , and s .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Bethmann, D., Kvasnicka, M. The institution of marriage . J Popul Econ 24, 1005–1032 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-010-0312-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-010-0312-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation