Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Life expectancy, money, and growth

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We examine the effect of an increase in life expectancy on portfolio choices of individuals and, thereby, on economic growth in a simple endogenous growth model populated by overlapping generations, in which money is introduced based on the money-in-the-utility-function approach. It is shown that an increase in longevity raises the balanced growth rate and lowers the inflation rate, offsetting the Tobin effect, if spillovers from accumulated capital to labor productivity sufficiently raise wage income and real savings, and, if not, it may retard economic growth and aggravate inflation. Under plausible conditions, the former will be the case.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. van der Ploeg and Alogoskoufis (1994) suggested that the birth of new generations and the absence of intergenerational bequests may bring about an adverse relationship between inflation and economic growth in a continuous time overlapping generations model. This relationship holds for our model, too.

  2. Some authors assume a linkage between life expectancy and spending on health care. See, for example, Ehrlich and Chuma (1990), Philipson and Becker (1998), and Kalemli-Ozcan (2002).

  3. The fertility decisions can be endogenized. If parents derive direct utility from the number of their children, the fertility decisions of parents and the effect of declining mortality on them are similar to those in Zhang et al. (2001) and Yakita (2001).

  4. It has been shown that with imperfect annuity markets and accidental bequests, the relation between mortality decline and economic growth can be nonmonotonic. See, for example, Zhang et al. (2003) and Miyazawa (2003).

  5. We assume in this study that the retirement age is given institutionally.

  6. This is a two-period-lived-agent version of the utility function of Mino and Shibata (1995). Drazen (1981), considering instead the case in which money provides utility in both periods of life, showed that the effect of inflation on capital may depend on the seigniorage transfer policy.

  7. We assume that an individual does not hold real balances at the end of his second period.

  8. For the interpretation, see, for example, Wigger (1999).

  9. We assume here that 0<μ<1, for example, on an annual base, but it is not necessarily needed for our result.

  10. We can see that condition Eq. (7) is satisfied when condition Eq. (19) holds. Even when the interest rate is negative, individuals are willing to hold real balances as long as the nominal interest rate is positive.

  11. This is a version of the AK model, and therefore, there is no transition. π is a jump variable.

  12. A greater η and/or a higher r tend to make the left-hand side smaller, while higher r is associated with higher ω/a under the assumption that 1>(af′/f)[1-(af″/f′)]. The condition is satisfied when f(a)=Aa α(0<A;0<α<1).

  13. We have (∂ɛ/∂π)−(∂ϕ/∂π)>0 (see Appendix). It should be noted that π may not be monotonic in λ when the growth rate of money supply, μ, is constant and relatively high enough for Eq. (19) to be satisfied. If the inflation rate reaches π=η[1/(1+r)+(1−η)]+(1−η)[μ/(ω/a)]-1, either from above or from below, an increase in life expectancy no longer affects the inflation rate and, thus, economic growth.

  14. The negative relation between growth and inflation is often documented in cross-country data, e.g., Gomme (1993). Roubini and Sala-i-Martin (1992) argued that the negative correlation is likely to be spurious as both are caused by policies of financial repression. The negative correlation obtained in our study is conditional on the life expectancy variable.

  15. A smaller η makes the inflation rate slightly lower and the growth rate slightly higher in each case. We have similar numerical results in the case of a CES production function.

  16. For a survey of different approaches and the results, see, for example, Orphanides and Solow (1990). Based on the cash-and-credit-goods approach with a cash-in-advance constraint a la Lucas and Stokey (1983) and Batina and Ihori (2000), we can show that an increase in life expectancy leads to higher growth and lower inflation.

References

  • Abel AB (1987) Optimal monetary growth. J Monet Econ 19:437–450

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow KJ (1962) The economic implications of learning by doing. Rev Econ Stud 29:155–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro RJ, Sala-i-Martin X (2004) Economic growth, 2nd edn. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Batina R, Ihori T (2000) Consumption tax policy and the taxation of capital income. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Chari VV, Manuelli RE, Jones LE (1995) The growth effects of monetary policy. Q Rev–Fed Reserve Bank Minneapolis 19:18–32

    Google Scholar 

  • de la Croix D, Licandro O (1999) Life expectancy and endogenous growth. Econ Lett 65:255–263

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drazen A (1981) Inflation and capital accumulation under a finite horizon. J Monet Econ 8:247–260

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ehrlich I, Chuma H (1990) A model of the demand for longevity and the value of life extension. J Polit Econ 98:761–782

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ehrlich I, Lui F (1991) Intergenerational trade, longevity, and economic growth. J Polit Econ 99:1029–1059

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gomme P (1993) Money and growth revisited: measuring the costs of inflation in an endogenous growth model. J Monet Econ 32:51–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman GM, Yanagawa N (1993) Asset bubbles and endogenous growth. J Monet Econ 31:3–19

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalemli-Ozcan S (2002) Does the mortality decline promote economic growth? J Econ Growth 7:411–443

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalemli-Ozcan S, Ryder HE, Weil DN (2000) Mortality decline, human capital investment, and economic growth. J Dev Econ 62:1–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee R, Tuljapurkar S (1997) Death and taxes: how longer life will affect social security. Demography 34:67–82

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas RE, Stokey NL (1983) Optimal fiscal and monetary policy in an economy without capital. J Monet Econ 12:55–93

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mino K, Shibata A (1995) Monetary policy, overlapping generations, and patterns of growth. Economica 62:179–194

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miyazawa K (2003) Demographic transition and income inequality in an accidental bequest model. Mimeo, Nanzan University

    Google Scholar 

  • Orphanides A, Solow RM (1990) Money, inflation and growth. In: Friedman BM, Hahn FH (eds) Handbook of monetary economics. North Holland, Amsterdam, pp 223–261

    Google Scholar 

  • Philipson TJ, Becker GS (1998) Old-age longevity and mortality: contingent claims. J Polit Econ 106:551–573

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer PM (1986) Increasing returns and long-run growth. J Polit Econ 94:1002–1037

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roubini N, Sala-i-Martin X (1992) Financial repression and economic growth. J Dev Econ 39:5–30

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van der Ploeg F, Alogoskoufis GS (1994) Money and endogenous growth. J Money Credit Bank 26:771–791

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wigger BU (1999) Public pensions and growth. Finanzarchiv 56:241–263

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (1993) World development report. World Bank, Washington, DC

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Yakita A (1989) The optimal rate of inflation and taxation. J Public Econ 38:369–385

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yakita A (2001) Uncertain lifetime, fertility and social security. J Popul Econ 14:635–640

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang J, Zhang J, Lee R (2001) Mortality decline and long-run economic growth. J Public Econ 80:485–507

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang J, Zhang J, Lee R (2003) Rising longevity, education, savings, and growth. J Dev Econ 70:83–101

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author thanks Kazutoshi Miyazawa, the referees and the editor of this journal, and the seminar participants at Chukyo University for their helpful comments and suggestions. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Akira Yakita.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Alessandro Cigno

Appendices

Uniqueness of balanced growth equilibrium

From Eq. (18),

$$\phi {\left( \pi \right)} \equiv {\left( {1 + \pi } \right)}\frac{\omega }{a}{\left[ {{\left( {1 + r} \right)}{\left( {1 + \pi } \right)}{\left( {1 - \frac{{1 + \rho }}{{2 + \rho - \lambda }}} \right)} - {\left( {1 - \eta \frac{{1 + \rho }}{{2 + \rho - \lambda }}} \right)}} \right]}$$

and

$$\varepsilon {\left( \pi \right)} \equiv {\left( {1 + \mu } \right)}{\left\{ {{\left[ {1 - {\left( {1 - \eta } \right)}\frac{{1 + \rho }}{{2 + \rho - \lambda }}\frac{\mu }{{1 + \mu }}} \right]}{\left( {1 + r} \right)}{\left( {1 + \pi } \right)} - 1} \right\}}$$

as depicted in Fig. 1. ϕ(π) is a quadratic function of π and has two intersections with the horizontal axis at −1 and \({\left\{ {{{\left[ {1 - \eta \frac{{1 + \rho }}{{2 + \rho - \lambda }}} \right]}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left[ {1 - \eta \frac{{1 + \rho }}{{2 + \rho - \lambda }}} \right]}} {{\left[ {{\left( {1 + r} \right)}{\left( {1 - \frac{{1 + \rho }}{{2 + \rho - \lambda }}} \right)}} \right]}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {{\left[ {{\left( {1 + r} \right)}{\left( {1 - \frac{{1 + \rho }}{{2 + \rho - \lambda }}} \right)}} \right]}}} \right\}} - 1\), while ɛ(π) is a line and intersects the abscissa at \({\left\{ {{\left( {1 + r} \right)}{\left[ {1 - {\left( {1 - \eta } \right)}\frac{{1 + \rho }}{{2 + \rho - \lambda }}\frac{\mu }{{1 + \mu }}} \right]}} \right\}}^{{ - 1}} - 1\). Since we can easily see that \({\left\{ {{{\left[ {1 - \eta \frac{{1 + \rho }}{{2 + \rho - \lambda }}} \right]}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left[ {1 - \eta \frac{{1 + \rho }}{{2 + \rho - \lambda }}} \right]}} {{\left[ {{\left( {1 + r} \right)}{\left( {1 - \frac{{1 + \rho }}{{2 + \rho - \lambda }}} \right)}} \right]}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {{\left[ {{\left( {1 + r} \right)}{\left( {1 - \frac{{1 + \rho }}{{2 + \rho - \lambda }}} \right)}} \right]}}} \right\}} - 1 > {\left\{ {{\left( {1 + r} \right)}{\left[ {1 - {\left( {1 - \eta } \right)}\frac{{1 + \rho }}{{2 + \rho - \lambda }}\frac{\mu }{{1 + \mu }}} \right]}} \right\}}^{{ - 1}} - 1\) for λ, η ∈ (0,1), Eq. (18) has two real roots, \(\pi _{{\ell }} \) and π h , such that \( - 1 < \pi _{{\ell }} < {\left\{ {{\left( {1 + r} \right)}{\left[ {1 - {\left( {1 - \eta } \right)}\frac{{1 + \rho }}{{2 + \rho - \lambda }}\frac{\mu }{{1 + \mu }}} \right]}} \right\}}^{{ - 1}} - 1 < \pi _{h} \) (see Fig. 1). With condition (19), however, the smaller root, \(\pi _{{\ell }} \), is not a solution to our model. Therefore, solving Eq. (18) for π, we obtain

$$\pi = \frac{{\frac{\omega }{a}{\left( {1 - \eta \frac{{1 + \rho }}{{2 + \rho - \lambda }}} \right)} + {\left( {1 + \mu } \right)}{\left( {1 + r} \right)}{\left\{ {1 - {\left( {1 - \eta } \right)}\frac{{1 + \rho }}{{2 + \rho - \lambda }}\frac{\mu }{{1 + \mu }}} \right\}} + D^{{1 \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 2}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} 2}} }}{{2\frac{\omega }{a}{\left( {1 + r} \right)}{\left( {1 - \frac{{1 + \rho }}{{2 + \rho - \lambda }}} \right)}}} - 1$$

where

$$D = {\left[ {\frac{\omega }{a}{\left( {1 - \eta \frac{{1 + \rho }}{{2 + \rho - \lambda }}} \right)} + {\left( {1 + \mu } \right)}{\left( {1 + r} \right)}{\left\{ {1 - {\left( {1 - \eta } \right)}\frac{{1 + \rho }}{{2 + \rho - \lambda }}\frac{\mu }{{1 + \mu }}} \right\}}} \right]}^{2} - 4\frac{\omega }{a}{\left( {1 + \mu } \right)}{\left( {1 + r} \right)}{\left( {1 - \frac{{1 + \rho }}{{2 + \rho - \lambda }}} \right)}$$

from which it follows that

$${\left( {1 + \pi } \right)}{\left( {1 + r} \right)}\frac{{2\omega }}{a}{\left( {1 - \frac{{1 + \rho }}{{2 + \rho - \lambda }}} \right)} - {\left[ {\frac{\omega }{a}{\left( {1 - \eta \frac{{1 + \rho }}{{2 + \rho - \lambda }}} \right)} + {\left( {1 + \mu } \right)}{\left( {1 + r} \right)}{\left\{ {1 - {\left( {1 - \eta } \right)}\frac{{1 + \rho }}{{2 + \rho - \lambda }}\frac{\mu }{{1 + \mu }}} \right\}}} \right]} > 0$$

This implies that \(\frac{{\partial \varepsilon }}{{\partial \pi }} - \frac{{\partial \phi }}{{\partial \pi }} > 0\). Thus, we have \(sign{\left( {\frac{{d\pi }}{{d\lambda }}} \right)} = sign{\left( {\frac{{\partial \phi }}{{\partial \lambda }} - \frac{{\partial \varepsilon }}{{\partial \lambda }}} \right)}.\)

Increase in the growth rate of money supply

Differentiating ɛ(π; μ), we have

$$\frac{{\partial \varepsilon }}{{\partial \mu }} = {\left( {1 + r} \right)}{\left( {1 + \pi } \right)}{\left\{ {1 - {\left( {1 - \eta } \right)}\frac{{1 + \rho }}{{2 + \rho - \lambda }}} \right\}} - 1$$

from which it follows that

$$sign{\left( {\frac{{\partial \varepsilon }}{{\partial \mu }}} \right)} = sign{\left[ {\pi - {\left\{ {{\left( {1 + r} \right)}^{{ - 1}} {\left[ {1 - {\left( {1 - \eta } \right)}\frac{{1 + \rho }}{{2 + \rho - \lambda }}} \right]}^{{ - 1}} - 1} \right\}}} \right]}$$

Since we can easily see that

$$\frac{{1 - \eta \frac{{1 + \rho }}{{2 + \rho - \lambda }}}}{{{\left( {1 + r} \right)}{\left( {1 - \frac{{1 + \rho }}{{2 + \rho - \lambda }}} \right)}}} - 1 > \frac{1}{{{\left( {1 + r} \right)}{\left[ {1 - {\left( {1 - \eta } \right)}\frac{{1 + \rho }}{{2 + \rho - \lambda }}} \right]}}} - 1$$

while taking Eq. (19) into account, it follows that

$$\pi - {\left\{ {{\left( {1 + r} \right)}^{{ - 1}} {\left[ {1 - {\left( {1 - \eta } \right)}\frac{{1 + \rho }}{{2 + \rho - \lambda }}} \right]}^{{ - 1}} - 1} \right\}} > 0$$

The curve ϕ(π) does not depend on μ, so the upward shift of ɛ(π, μ) increases the inflation rate.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Yakita, A. Life expectancy, money, and growth. J Popul Econ 19, 579–592 (2006). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-005-0017-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-005-0017-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation