Skip to main content
Log in

Employer preferences for long-term union contracts

  • Articles
  • Published:
Journal of Labor Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In recent years, the American industrial relations system has undergone considerable stress. One byproduct of a stressful period is that old ways of conducting industrial relations are being increasingly questioned. The fact that questions are raised, however, does not necessarily mean that the climate for change is receptive to all suggestions. In this paper we provide evidence that the management community would strongly oppose recent suggestions for the abandonment of long-term collective bargaining contracts.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  1. Arthur M. Okun, “Efficient Disinflationary Policies,”American Economic Review 68 (May 1978): 348–52.

    Google Scholar 

  2. Daniel J. B. Mitchell, “Gain-Sharing: An Anti-Inflation Reform,”Challenge 25 (July–August 1982): 18–25.

    Google Scholar 

  3. There are, in turn, two streams within the implicit contracting literature. Some writers emphasize turnover and transactions costs. See, for example, Arthur M. Okun,Prices and Quantities: A Macroeconomic Analysis (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1981), especially chapters 2 and 3; and

    Google Scholar 

  4. Michael H. Riordan and Michael L. Wachter, “What Do Implicit Contracts Do?” in Barbara D. Dennis, ed.,Proceedings of the Thirty-Fifth Annual Meeting, Industrial Relations Research Association, December 28–30, 1982 (Madison: IRRA, 1983): 291–98. Others emphasize risk shifting from employees to employer.

    Google Scholar 

  5. Robert E. Hall and David M. Lilien, “Efficient Wage Bargains Under Uncertain Supply and Demand,”American Economic Review 69 (December 1979): 868–79.

    Google Scholar 

  6. Daniel J. B. Mitchell, “Union Wage Determination: Policy Implications and Outlook,”Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 3 (1978): 537–591;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Wayne Vroman, “Union Contracts and Money Wage Changes in U.S. Manufacturing Industries,”Quarterly Journal of Economics XVII (November 1982): 571–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Robert J. Gordon, “Why U.S. Wage and Employment Behavior Differs from that in Britain and Japan,”Economic Journal 92 (March 1982): 13–44;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Jeffrey D. Sachs, “Wages, Profits, and Macroeconomic Adjustment: A Comparative Study,”Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2 (1979): 269–319;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Robert J. Gordon, “A Century of Evidence on Wage and Price Stickiness in the United States, the United Kingdom, and Japan” in James Tobin, ed.,Macroeconomic, Prices, and Quantities (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1983): 85–133. Some authors have simply noted signs that the U.S. is characterized by greater nominal wage rigidity than other countries without explicitly connecting this phenomenon to union contracts.

    Google Scholar 

  11. Dennis Grubb, Richard Jackman, and Richard Layard, “Wage Rigidity and Unemployment in OECD Countries,”European Economic Review 21 (March/April 1983): 11–39;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. William H. Branson and Julio J. Rotemberg, “International Adjustment with Wage Rigidity,”European Economic Review 13 (May 1980): 309–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Barry Bosworth, “Policy Choices for Controlling Inflation,”Alternatives for the 1980s 1 (1981), a publication of the Center for Democratic Policy (now the Center for National Policy), p. 21;

    Google Scholar 

  14. Lester Thurow, “Thurow’s Third Way,”Economist, January 23–29, 1982, p. 32;

  15. Felix Rohatyn, “Time for a Change,”New York Review of Books 30 (August 18, 1983), p. 48. See also the remarks of Joel Popkin reported in “Inflation Deceleration Seen Leaving CPI Rate at 8 Percent for 1982, 1983,”Daily Labor Report (May 11, 1982), p. A-10. Some of the criticism has been aimed at cost-of-living escalator clauses which are linked to long-term contracts. See Amitai Etzioni, “One Way to Keep Inflation Down,”Newsweek, May 2, 1983, p. 17. Indeed, Thurow appears to believe (incorrectly) that all long-term contracts have escalators. (See his remarks in the article cited above: “Without indexed contracts nobody would sign a three-year contract.”)

    Google Scholar 

  16. On concession bargaining, see Daniel J. B. Mitchell, “Recent Union Contract Concessions,”Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1 (1982): 165–201.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. For a review of the literature and some independent evidence, see Daniel J. B. Mitchell, “Wage Flexibility: Then and Now,” unpublished working paper number 65, UCLA Institute of Industrial Relations, December 1983.

  18. Sanford M. Jacoby and Daniel J. B. Mitchell, “Development of Contractual Features of the Union-Management Relationship,”Labor Law Journal 33 (August 1982): 512–18.

    Google Scholar 

  19. As Herschel I. Grossman put it, “The optimism prevalent in the mid-sixties, associated most vividly with the idea of fine tuning the macro-economy, has soured in the face of recession and inflation in the seventies.” See his chapter on “Rational Expectations, Business Cycles and Government Behavior” in Stanley Fischer, ed.,Rational Expectations and Economic Policy (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1980), p. 6.

    Google Scholar 

  20. Sanford M. Jacoby and Daniel J. B. Mitchell, “Does Implicit Contracting Explain Explicit Contracting?” in Barbara D. Dennis, ed.,Proceedings of the Thirty-Fifth Annual Meeting, Industrial Relations Research Association, December 28–30, 1982 (Madison: IRRA, 1983): 319–28.

    Google Scholar 

  21. U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics,Earnings and Other Characteristics of Organized Workers, May 1980, Bulletin 2105 (Washington: GPO, 1981), p. 6.

    Google Scholar 

  22. Less than 1 percent of workers under “major” private union contracts were covered by contracts of 12 months or less in 1980. See U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics,Characteristics of Major Collective Bargaining Agreements, January 1, 1980, Bulletin 2095 (Washington: GPO, 1981), p. 14. However, the proportion would probably be somewhat larger were complete data available on smaller units and on the public sector.

    Google Scholar 

  23. John B. Taylor, “Union Wage Settlements During a Disinflation,”American Economic Review 73 (December 1983): 981–93.

    Google Scholar 

  24. W. S. Woytinsky,Labor and Management Look at Collective Bargaining (New York: Twentieth Century Fund, 1949): 37–52;

    Google Scholar 

  25. Frederick H. Harbison, “The General Motors-United Auto Workers Agreement of 1950,”Journal of Political Economy 58 (October 1950): 397–411;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Joseph Garbarino,Wage-Policy and Long-Term Contracts (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1962): 15–19.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Jacoby and Mitchell, “Does Implicit Contracting Explain Explicit Contracting?”Labor Law Journal 33 (August 1982): pp. 324–325.

    Google Scholar 

  28. Jacoby and Mitchell, “Development of Contractual Features of the Union-Management Relationship,”Labor Law Journal 33 (August 1982): p. 515.

    Google Scholar 

  29. For a full discussion of these issues, see Charles R. Perry, Andrew M. Kramer, and Thomas J. Schneider,Operating During Strikes (Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Industrial Research Unit, 1982): 101–109.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Jacoby, S.M., Mitchell, D.J.B. Employer preferences for long-term union contracts. Journal of Labor Research 5, 215–228 (1984). https://doi.org/10.1007/BF02685074

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/BF02685074

Keywords

Navigation