Skip to main content
Log in

Constitutional choice for the control of water pollution

  • Published:
Constitutional Political Economy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Before passage of the Clean Water Act, water pollution was controlled by the common law of nuisance and the law of water rights. Had the common law not been superseded, it might have provided more ecologically sound pollution control than has occurred under the command-and-control statutory regime. The Clean Water Act imposes mechanical definitions and is subject to political interference. In contrast, the principle of the common law lies in its evolutionary and competitive nature, which is consistent with the market process.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Anderson, T.L. (ed) (1983)Water Rights: Scarce Resource Allocation, Bureaucracy, and the Environment. San Francisco: Pacific Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W. (1972) “On Taxation and Control of Externalities.”American Economic Review 62 (June): 307–322.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bone, R. (1986) “Normative Theory and Legal Doctrine in American Nuisance Law: 1950–1920.”Southern California Law Review 50: 1101–1226.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bosso, C. (1987)Pesticides and Politics. University of Pittsburgh Press.

  • Bovard, J. (1989)The Farm Fiasco. San Francisco: ICS Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J.M. (1969)Cost and Choice. Chicago: Markham.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J.M. (1990) “The Domain of Constitutional Economics.”Constitutional Political Economy 1(1): 1–18.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J.M. and G. Tullock (1975) “‘Polluters’ Profit and Political Response: Direct Controls versus Taxes.American Economic Review 65 (March): 139–147.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, P. (1971) “Theories of Water Pollution Litigation.”Wisconsin Law Review: 738–816.

  • General Accounting Office (1991a)Observations on the EPA and State Enforcement Under the Clean Water Act. GAO/T-REC-91-53 (May 14).

  • General Accounting Office (1991b)Environmental Enforcement. GAO/RECD-91-166 (June).

  • Goldfarb, W. (1988)Water Law (2d ed.) 63.

  • Hahn, R. and R. Stavins (1990) “Incentive-Based Environmental Regulation.”Ecology Law Quarterly 18: 1–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodas, D. (1988) “Private Actions for Public Nuisance: Common Law Citizen Suits for Relief from Environmental Harm.”Ecology Law Quarterly 16: 883–908.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jorgensen, E. (ed) (1989)The Poisoned Well: New Strategies for Groundwater Protection.

  • Menell, P. (1991) “The Limitations of Legal Institutions for Addressing Environmental Risks.”Journal of Economic Perspectives 5(3): 93–113.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meiners, R. and B. Yandle (eds) (1989)Regulation and the Reagan Era. New York: Holmes & Meier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prosser, W. (1955)Torts. (2d ed.) 405.

  • Rabin, E. (1977) “Nuisance Law: Rethinking Fundamental Assumptions.Virginia Law Review 63: 1299–1384.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Staaf R. and B. Yandle (1991) “Common Law, Statute Law, and Liability Rules.” In: R. Meiners and B. Yandle (eds) (1991)The Economic Consequences of Liability Rules. Westport, CT: Quorum Books: 11–28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stavins, R. and A. Jaffe (1990) “Unintended Impacts of Public Investments on Private Decisions: The Depletion of Forested Wetlands.”American Economic Review 80: (June) 337–352.

    Google Scholar 

  • U.S. Congress. House. Committee on Public Works (1971)Hearings on Water Pollution Control Legislation. 42d Cong. (Dec. 7–10).

Legal references

  • Arkansas v. Oklahoma, 60 LW 4176 (1992).

  • Garland Grain Co. v. D-C Home Owners Improvement Assn., 393 SW2d 635 (Tex. Civ. App., 1965).

  • Georgia v. Tennessee Copper Co., 206 U.S. 230 (1907).

  • Hallstrom v. Tillamook County, 110 S.Ct. 304 (1989).

  • Illinois v. Milwaukee, 406 U.S. 91 (1972).

  • Milwaukee v. Illinois, 451 U.S. 304 (1981).

  • Missouri v. Illinois, 200 U.S. 496 (1906).

  • Restatement (Second) of Torts §821B (1977). Restatement (Second) of Torts §829A.

  • Rylands v. Fletcher, L.R. 3 H.L. 330 (1868).

  • Stoddard v. Western Carolina Regional Sewer Authority, 784 F.2d 1200 (1986).

  • Tennessee v. Champion Int'l Corp., 479 U.S. 1061, 107 S.Ct. 944 (1987).

  • Texas v. Pankey, 441 F.2d 236 (10th Cir., 1971).

  • Trevett v. Prison Association, 98 Va. 332, 336; 36 S.E. 373, 374 (1900), quoting H. Wood, 1 Nuisances §427 (3d ed. 1893).

  • Village of Euclid v. Ambler Realty, 272 US 365 (1926).

  • Village of Watsonville v. SCA Services, 426 N.E.2d 824 (1981).

  • Weston Paper Co. v. Pope, 155 Ind. 394, 57 N.E. 719 (1900).

  • Whalen v. Union Bag & Paper Co., 208 N.Y. 1, 5, 101 N.E. 805, 806 (1913).

  • Wood v. Picillo, 433 A.2d 1244 (1982).

  • 4 Water and Water Rights 45 §30.02(c) (1991 ed.) Charlottesville: Michie.

  • 5 Water and Water Rights §49.03(b) n. 43 (1991 ed.) Charlottesville: Michie.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Additional information

Meiners thanks the Political Economy Research Center of Bozeman, Montana for support during his visit in 1992. We thank Terry Anderson, Robert Natelson, Jane Shaw and Richard Stroup for helpful comments. We owe a large intellectual debt to Bob Staaf, who made us think about the relationship between competitive markets and the common law.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Meiners, R.E., Yandle, B. Constitutional choice for the control of water pollution. Constit Polit Econ 3, 359–380 (1992). https://doi.org/10.1007/BF02393141

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/BF02393141

Keywords

Navigation