Atlantic Economic Journal

, Volume 28, Issue 2, pp 150–163 | Cite as

Fluctuations in productivity growth rates and input utilization in U.S. manufacturing

  • Daniel J. Ryan
Articles

Abstract

Recent work suggests that the utilization rate of inputs (that is, the intensity with which inputs are used) varies over time and partly explains procyclical productivity. To confirm this, the panel data of the “NBER Manufacturing Productivity Database” (450 4-digit industries from 1958 to 1991) [Bartelsman and Gray, 1994] were analyzed to determine the year-by-year fluctuations in total factor productivity growth rates and the utilization rates of nonmaterial inputs. The utilization rate was found to be procyclical. When the gross domestic product (GDP) growth rate is 1 percentage point above normal, the utilization rate increases 2.5 percent. After this correction, productivity growth rates are still found to be procyclical, though its correlation with GDP growth is half that of the uncorrected Solow residual. That is, demand shocks can explain half of the procyclicality of productivity growth rates, but real business cycles still cannot be ruled out. Lastly, the results are compared with the Federal Reserve's capacity utilization statistics. It is shown that the latter actually measures a combination of capacity utilization and productivity shifts and, hence, overstates changes in capacity utilization.

Keywords

Gross Domestic Product Panel Data Business Cycle Total Factor Productivity Factor Productivity 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Bartelsman, Eric; Gray, Wayne. “NBER Manufacturing Productivity Database,” mimeo, ftp://nber.harvard.edu/pub/nber, December 1994.Google Scholar
  2. Basu, Susanto. “Intermediate Goods and Business Cycles: Implications for Productivity and Welfare,”American Economic Review, 85, 3, June 1995, pp. 512–31.Google Scholar
  3. __. “Procyclical Productivity: Increasing Returns or Cyclical Utilization?,”Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111, 3, August 1996, pp. 719–51.Google Scholar
  4. Basu, Susanto; Fernald, John G. “Are Apparent Productive Spillovers a Figment of Specification Error?,”Journal of Monetary Economics, 36, 2, August 1995, pp. 165–88.Google Scholar
  5. Bils, M. “The Cyclical Behavior of Marginal Cost and Price,”American Economic Review, 77, 5, December 1987, pp. 838–55.Google Scholar
  6. Burnside, Craig. “Production Function Regressions, Returns to Scale, and Externalities,”Journal of Monetary Economics, 37, 2, April 1996, pp. 177–201.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Burnside, Craig; Eichenbaum, Martin; Rebelo, Sergio. “Labor Hoarding and the Business Cycle,”Journal of Political Economy, 101, 2, April 1993, pp. 245–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. __. “Capital Utilization and Returns to Scale,” in Julio J. Rotemberg; Ben S. Bernanke, eds.,NBER Macroeconomics Annual, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1995.Google Scholar
  9. Carey, Kevin. “The Relationship Between Inventory Investment and Total Factor Productivity Growth: Cost Shocks or Demand Shocks,”Economics Letters, 51, 2, May 1996, pp. 219–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Chevalier, Judith A.; Scharfstein, David S. “Liquidity Constraints and the Cyclical Behavior of Markups,”American Economic Review, 85, 2, May 1995, pp. 390–6.Google Scholar
  11. __. “Capital-Market Imperfections and Countercyclical Markups: Theory and Evidence,”American Economic Review, 86, 4, September 1996, pp. 703–25.Google Scholar
  12. Domowitz, Ian; Hubbard, R. Glenn; Petersen, Bruce C. “Business Cycles and the Relationship Between Concentration and Price-Cost Margins,Rand Journal of Economics, 17, 1986, pp. 1–17.Google Scholar
  13. __. “Market Structure and Cyclical Fluctuations in U.S. Manufacturing,”Review of Economics and Statistics, 70, 1988, pp. 55–66.Google Scholar
  14. “Economic Report of the President.”National, Economic, Social, and Environmental Data Bank, CD-ROM, Washington, DC: U.S. Dept. of Commerce, 1999.Google Scholar
  15. Fay, Jon A.; Medoff, James L. “Labor and Output Over the Business Cycle: Some Direct Evidence,”American Economic Review, 75, 4, September 1985, pp. 638–55.Google Scholar
  16. Farmer, Roger E. A.; Guo, Jang-Ting. “Real Business Cycles and the Animal Spirits Hypothesis,”Journal of Economic Theory, 63, 1, June 1994, pp. 42–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Green, E. J.; Porter, R. H. “Noncooperative Collusion Under Imperfect Price Information,”Econometrica, 52, 1984, pp. 87–100.Google Scholar
  18. Hall, Robert E. “The Relation Between Price and Marginal Cost in U.S. Industry,”Journal of Political Economy, 96, 1988, pp. 921–47.Google Scholar
  19. __. “Invariance Properties of Solow's Productivity Residual,” in P. Diamond, ed.,Growth/Productivity/Unemployment: Essays to Celebrate Bob Solow's Birthday, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1990.Google Scholar
  20. Haskel, Jonathan; Martin, Christopher; Small, Ian. “Price, Marginal Cost and the Business Cycle,”Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 57, 1, February 1995, pp. 25–41.Google Scholar
  21. Jorgenson, Dale W.; Griliches, Zvi. “The Explanation of Productivity Change,”Review of Economic Studies, 34, 3, July 1967, pp. 249–83.Google Scholar
  22. Kamerschen, David R.; Park, Jae-Hee. “An Alternative Approach to Market Structure and the Markup Ratio,”Applied Economics, 25, 1, 1993, pp. 111–24.Google Scholar
  23. Kwoka, J. E., Jr. “The Effect of Market Growth and Contraction on Industry Price-Cost Margins,”Eastern Economic Journal, 16, 3, July–September 1990, pp. 221–7.Google Scholar
  24. Lebow, David E. “Imperfect Competition and Business Cycles: An Empirical Investigation,”Economic Inquiry, 30, 1, January 1992, pp. 177–93.Google Scholar
  25. Mattey, Joe; Strongin, Steve. “Factor Utilization and Margins for Adjusting Output: Evidence from Manufacturing Plants,”Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Economic Review, 2, 1997, pp. 3–17.Google Scholar
  26. Morrison, Catherine J. “Unraveling the Productivity Growth Slowdown in the United States, Canada and Japan: The Effects of Subequilibrium, Scale Economies and Markups,”Review of Economics and Statistics, 74, 3, August 1992, pp. 381–93.Google Scholar
  27. Rotemberg, Julio J.; Saloner, Garth. “A Supergame-Theoretic Model of Price Wars During Booms,”American Economic Review, 76, 1986, pp. 390–407.Google Scholar
  28. Rotemberg, Julio J.; Summers, Lawrence. “Inflexible Prices and Procyclical Productivity,”Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105, 4, November 1990, pp. 851–74.Google Scholar
  29. Rotemberg, Julio J.; Woodford, Michael. “Markups and the Business Cycle,” in O. Blanchard; S. Fischer, eds.,NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1991, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1991.Google Scholar
  30. Ryan, Daniel J. “The Behavior of Productivity Growth Rates and Price-Cost Margins During Contractions and Expansions,”Applied Economics, 29, 7, July 1997, pp. 889–93.Google Scholar
  31. Sbordone, Argia M. “Interpreting the Procyclical Productivity of Manufacturing Sectors: External Effects or Labor Hoarding?,”Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 29, 1, February 1997, pp. 26–45.Google Scholar
  32. Shapiro, Matthew D. “Macroeconomic Implications of Variation in the Workweek of Capital,”Brookings Papers on Economics Activity, 2, 1996, pp. 79–119.Google Scholar
  33. Solow, Robert M. “Technical Change and the Aggregate Production Function, ”Review of Economics and Statistics, 39, August 1957, pp. 312–20.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© International Atlantic Economic Society 2000

Authors and Affiliations

  • Daniel J. Ryan
    • 1
  1. 1.Temple UniversityUSA

Personalised recommendations