Experimental Economics

, Volume 3, Issue 1, pp 11–29 | Cite as

Learning to accept in ultimatum games: Evidence from an experimental design that generates low offers

  • John A. List
  • Todd L. Cherry
Article

Abstract

Focusing on responder behavior, we report panel data findings from both low and high stakes ultimatum bargaining games. Whereas Slonim and Roth (1998) find that offers are rejected fairly equally across rounds in both low and high stakes games, we find that learning does take place, but only when there is sufficient money on the table. The disparate results can be reconciled when one considers the added power that our experimental design provides-detecting subtle temporal differences in responder behavior requires a data generation process that induces a significant number of proportionally low offers.

Keywords

bargaining games responder behavior learning 

JEL Classification

C7 C9 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Bolton, G. (1991). “A Comparative Model of Bargaining: Theory and Evidence.”American Economic Review. 81, 1096–1136.Google Scholar
  2. Chamberlain, G. (1980). “Analysis of Covariance with Qualitative Data.”Review of Economic Studies. 47, 225–238.Google Scholar
  3. Cherry, T.L. and List, J.A. (2000). “Self-interest in Bargaining Games when Initial Wealth is Earned.” Working paper, University of Central Florida.Google Scholar
  4. Conlisk, J. (1996). “Why Bounded Rationality?”Journal of Economic Literature. 34, 669–700.Google Scholar
  5. Forsythe, R., Horowitz, J., Savin, N.E., and Sefton, M. (1994). “Replicability, Fairness and Pay in Experiments with Simple Bargaining Games.”Games and Economic Behavior. 6(3), 347–369.Google Scholar
  6. Fudenberg, D. and Levine, D. (1997). “Measuring Players' Losses in Experimental Games.”Quarterly Journal of Economics. 112, 507–536.Google Scholar
  7. Guth, W., Schmittberger, R., and Schwartz, R. (1982). “An Experimental Analysis of Ultimatum Bargaining.”Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization. 3, 367–388.Google Scholar
  8. Hoffman, E., McCabe, K.A., Shachat, K., and Smith, V.L. (1994). “Preferences, Property Rights and Anonymity in Bargaining Games.”Games and Economic Behavior. 7(3), 346–380.Google Scholar
  9. Hoffman, E., McCabe, K.A., and Smith, V.L. (1996a). “On Expectations and the Monetary Stakes in Ultimatum Games.”International Journal of Game Theory. 25(3), 289–302.Google Scholar
  10. Hoffman, E., McCabe, K.A., and Smith, V.L. (1996b). “Social Distance and Other-Regarding Behavior in Dictator Games.”American Economic Review. 86(3), 653–660.Google Scholar
  11. List, J.A. and Lucking-Reilly, D. (forthcoming). “Demand Reduction in a Multi-Unit Auction: Evidence from a Sportscard Field Experiment.”American Economic Review. Google Scholar
  12. List, J.A. and Shogren, J.F. (1998). “Experimental Calibration of the Difference Between Actual and Hypothetical Reported Valuations.”Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization. 37(2), 193–205.Google Scholar
  13. Roth, A.E. and Erev, I. (1995). “Learning in Extensive-Form Games: Experimental Data and Simple Dynamic Models in the Intermediate Term.”Games and Economic Behavior. 8, 164–212.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Economic Science Association 2000

Authors and Affiliations

  • John A. List
    • 1
  • Todd L. Cherry
    • 2
  1. 1.Department of EconomicsUniversity of Central FloridaOrlandoUSA
  2. 2.Department of EconomicsAppalachian State UniversityBooneUSA

Personalised recommendations