Skip to main content
Log in

Self-selecting tariffs under pure preferences among tariffs

  • Published:
Journal of Regulatory Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The behavioral assumptions for welfare analysis of self-selecting tariffs are generalized to be consistent with those maintained in empirical models of tariff choice. When customers have pure preferences among tariffs, it is shown that the optimal self-selecting tariffs provide strictly greater welfare than mandatory marginal cost prices, contain marginal prices that do not equal marginal cost, and can Pareto dominate an existing tariff. As an illustration of the theoretical results, optimal self-selecting tariffs are calculated empirically for a local telephone company.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Baumol, W., and D. Bradford, 1970. “Optimal Departures from Marginal Cost Pricing,”American Economic Review 67(3): 350–365.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brown, G. and D. Sibley, 1986.The Theory of Public Utility Pricing, Cambridge University Press.

  • Coase, R., 1946. “The Marginal Cost Controversy,”Economica 13: 169–189.

    Google Scholar 

  • Faulhaber, G., and Panzar, J., 1977. “Optional Two-Part Tariffs with Self-Selection,” Bell Laboratories Economic Discussion Paper No. 74.

  • Hausman, J. and D. Wise, 1978. “A Conditional Probit Model for Qualitative Choice: Discrete Decisions Recognizing Interdependence and Heterogenous Preferences,”Econometrica. 48(2): 403–426.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hobson, M. and R. Spady, 1987. “Demand for Local Telephone Service Under Optional Local Measured Service,” technical memorandum Bell Communications Research.

  • Kling, J., 1984. “Estimation of Local Exchange Elasticities,” report, Michigan Bell Telephone Company.

  • Kling, J. and S. van der Ploeg, 1988. “Estimating Local Telephone Call Elasticities with a Stochastic Model of Class of Service and Usage Choice,” paper presented at the Seventh International Conference of the International Telecommunications Society, MIT.

  • Leland, H. and R. Meyer, 1976, “Monopoly Pricing Structure with Imperfect Discrimination,”Bell Journal of Economics 7: 449–462.

    Google Scholar 

  • Littlechild, S., 1975, “Two Part Tariffs and Consumption Externalities,”Bell Journal of Economics 6: 661–670.

    Google Scholar 

  • Luce, R., 1959.Individual Choice Behavior, New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • MacKie-Mason, J., 1990. “Optional Time-of-Use Pricing Can Be Pareto Superior or Pareto Inferior,”Economic Letters, 33: 363–367.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marschak, J., 1960. “Binary Choice Constraints on Random Utility Indicators,” in K. Arrow, ed.,Stanford Symposium on Mathematical Methods in the Social Sciences, Stanford University Press.

  • McFadden, D., 1973. “Conditional Logit Analysis of Qualitative Choice behavior,” in P. Zarembka, ed.,Frontiers in Econometrics, New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McFadden, D., 1981. “Econometric Model of Probabilistic Choice,” in Manski and McFadden, eds.,Structural Analysis of Discrete Data with Econometric Applications, MIT Press.

  • McFadden, D., 1987. “Regression-Based Specification Tests for the Multinomial Logit Model,”Journal of Econometrics 34: 63–82.

    Google Scholar 

  • McFadden, D., K. Train, and W. Tye, 1977. “An Application of Diagnostic Tests for the Independence from Irrelevant Alternatives Property of the Multinomial Logit Model,”Transportation Research Record 637: 39–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ng, Y. and M. Weissner, 1974. “Optimal Pricing with a Budget Constraint: The Case of the Two-Part Tariff,”Review of Economic Studies 41.

  • Panzar, J., 1977. “The Pareto Domination of Usage-Insensitive Pricing,” in H. Dorrick, ed.,Proceedings of the Sixth Annual Telecommunications Policy Research Conference, Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Small, K., and H. Rosen, 1981. “Applied Welfare Economics with Discrete Choice Models,”Econometrica 49: 105–130.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tardiff, T., 1989. “Consumer Welfare with Discrete Choice Models: Implications for Flat versus Measured Local Telephone Service,” report, National Economic Research Associates.

  • Thurstone, L., 1927. “A Law of Comparative Judgment,”Psychology Review 34: 273–286.

    Google Scholar 

  • Train, K., 1986.Qualitative Choice Analysis, MIT Press.

  • Train, K., D. McFadden, and M. Ben-Akiva, 1987. “The Demand for Local Telephone Service: A Fully Discrete Model of Residential Calling Patterns and Service Choice,”Rand Journal of Economics 18(1): 109–123.

    Google Scholar 

  • Train, K., M. Ben-Akiva, and T. Atherton, 1989. “Consumption Patterns and Self-Selecting Tariffs,”Review of Economics and Statistics 71: 62–73.

    Google Scholar 

  • Train, K., and G. Mehrez, 1994. “Optional Time-of-Use Prices for Electricity: Econometric Analysis of Surplus and Pareto Impacts.”Rand Journal of Economics 25 (No. 2, forthcoming).

  • Willig, R., 1978. “Pareto Superior Non-Linear Outlay Schedules,”Bell Journal of Economics 9:56–69.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, R., 1991.Nonlinear Pricing, Oxford University Press.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Train, K.E. Self-selecting tariffs under pure preferences among tariffs. J Regul Econ 6, 247–264 (1994). https://doi.org/10.1007/BF01064654

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/BF01064654

Keywords

Navigation