Political Behavior

, Volume 8, Issue 1, pp 3–20 | Cite as

Preemptive and reactive spending in U.S. House races

  • Edie N. Goldenberg
  • Michael W. Traugott
  • Frank R. Baumgartner
Article

Abstract

This paper examines the spending behavior of candidates for the U.S. House of Representatives. Particular attention is paid to the timing of receipts and expenditures over the complete 2-year election cycle. Incumbents raise and spend large amounts of money very early in the race, and this preemptive spending may have a great impact on the selection of challengers and therefore on electoral outcomes. In addition, a model of reactive spending is tested for the general election period. Incumbents' expenditures are a function of the underlying partisan division in the district, the strength of the challenge, and candidates' feelings of vulnerability. Incumbents are strategic actors who attempt to maximize their chances of reelection. Early in the term, they spend preemptively in an effort to influence the selection of their challengers. Later in the term, they spend in reaction to the strength of their challengers' campaign. The role of money in congressional campaigns is neither simple nor direct. More attention needs to be given to the strategic uses of money in the period leading up to the general election campaign as well as to the dynamics of receipts and expenditures over an entire election cycle.

Keywords

General Election Electoral Outcome Strategic Actor Election Campaign Election Cycle 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Barone, Michael, Ujifusa, Grant, and Matthew, Douglas (1979).The Almanac of American Politics 1980. New York: E. P. Dutton.Google Scholar
  2. Campbell, James E., Alford, John R., and Henry, Keith (1984). Television markets and congressional elections.Legislative Studies Quarterly 9:665–678.Google Scholar
  3. Converse, Philip E. (1966). The concept of a normal vote. In Angus Campbell, Philip E. Converse, Warren Miller, and Donald E. Stokes (eds.),Elections and the Political Order, pp. 9–39. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
  4. Cover, Albert D. (1977). One good term deserves another: The advantage of incumbency in congressional elections.American Journal of Political Science 21:523–542.Google Scholar
  5. Cover, Albert D., and Brumberg, Bruce S. (1982). Baby books and ballots: The impact of congressional mail on constituent opinions.American Political Science Review 76:347–359.Google Scholar
  6. Fenno, Richard F. Jr. (1978).Home Style: House Members in their Districts. Boston: Little, Brown.Google Scholar
  7. Fiorina, Morris P. (1974).Representatives, Roll Calls and Constituencies. Lexington, Mass.: D. C. Heath.Google Scholar
  8. Fiorina, Morris P. (1977). The case of the vanishing marginals: The bureaucracy did it.American Political Science Review 71:177–181.Google Scholar
  9. Goldenberg, Edie N., and Traugott, Michael W. (1984).Campaigning for Congress. Washington: Congressional Quarterly Press.Google Scholar
  10. Hinckley, Barbara (1980). House reelections and Senate defeats: The role of the challenger.British Journal of Political Science 10:441–460.Google Scholar
  11. Jacobson, Gary C. (1978). The effects of campaign spending in congressional elections.American Political Science Review 72:469–491.Google Scholar
  12. Jacobson, Gary C. (1980a).Money in Congressional Elections. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  13. Jacobson, Gary C. (1980b). Congressional elections, 1978: The case of the vanishing challengers. Paper presented at the Conference on Congressional Elections, Rice University and the University of Houston, Houston, Texas, Jan. 10–12.Google Scholar
  14. Jacobson, Gary C. (1981). Strategic politicians and congressional elections, 1946–1980. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, New York, Sept. 3–6.Google Scholar
  15. Jacobson, Gary C. and Kernell, Samuel E. (1982).Strategy and Choice in Congressional Elections. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  16. Lardner, George Jr. (1985, April 29). How much for a House seat?The Washington Post National Weekly Edition.Google Scholar
  17. Mayhew, David R. (1974a).Congress: The Electoral Connection. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  18. Mayhew, David R. (1974b). Congressional elections: The case of the vanishing marginals.Polity 6:295–317.Google Scholar
  19. Noble, Kenneth B. (1983, April 5). Some in House using excess election cash for expensive living.New York Times.Google Scholar
  20. Peters, J. G., and Welch, S. (1980). The effects of charges of corruption on voting behavior in congressional elections.American Political Science Review 74:697–708.Google Scholar
  21. Ragsdale, Lyn (1981). Incumbent popularity, challenger invisibility, and congressional voters.Legislative Studies Quarterly 6:201–218.Google Scholar
  22. Traugott, Michael W., and Goldenberg, Edie N. (1981). Normal vote analysis of U.S. congressional elections.Legislative Studies Quarterly 6:247–257.Google Scholar
  23. Welch, William P. (1980). The allocation of political monies: economic interest groups.Public Choice 35:97–120.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Agathon Press, Inc. 1986

Authors and Affiliations

  • Edie N. Goldenberg
    • 1
  • Michael W. Traugott
    • 1
  • Frank R. Baumgartner
    • 1
  1. 1.Center for Political StudiesThe University of MichiganUSA

Personalised recommendations