Advertisement

European Journal of Law and Economics

, Volume 3, Issue 3, pp 221–247 | Cite as

Economic incentives for the self-regulation of the release of price-sensitive information

  • John Holland
Article
  • 63 Downloads

Abstract

Companies, as primary disseminators of information, and financial institutions, as major recipients, have economic incentives to self-regulate the transmission and usage of price-sensitive information. These include increased (lost) reputation costs and adverse share price penalties arising from poor management of information disclosure. The economic motivation for self-regulation is seen as conceptually linked to but distinct from legislative changes. Self-regulation has the strong support of economic efficiency arguments, whereas recent additional new legislative changes do not. This article examines a major corporate and institutional response to the new regulatory climate—to internalize part of the regulatory process during their regular relationship communications. Relationships between the case companies and institutions already exist for transaction purposes. They are used as a convenient and low-cost means to pursue self-regulation and to avoid errors of price-sensitive information release. This self-regulatory process is illustrated using case material. It is clear from the response pattern presented that the development of a self-regulatory framework by the parties has been an iterative one. The corporate and institutional systems that have been evolving seem to be significantly influenced by the regulatory trends. The regulatory changes appear to have played a role in increasing market costs incurred by those companies with poor stock market communication practices. The article ends by arguing that new proposals to change in the formal regulatory system should recognize that further legislation is unlikely to improve the poor prosecution record. Nevertheless, legislative changes can combine with and buttress the self-regulation process to create an effective regulatory system.

Keywords

Private disclosure price sensitive information economic incentive self regulation 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Bain, S. (1993).Scotland on Sunday, April 4, p. 15.Google Scholar
  2. Bain, S. (1994). “Business Week.”Scotland on Sunday, February 20, p. 2.The Economist. (1993). May 22, p. 100.Google Scholar
  3. Fenn, P., Alistair McGuire, and Dan Prentice. (1991). “Information Imbalances and the Security Markets.” InEuropean Insider Dealing (ch. 1). London: Butterworths.Google Scholar
  4. Franks, J., and S. Schaefer. (1994). “The Costs and Effectiveness of the U.K. Financial Regulatory System.” Paper presented at a workshop on the Assessment of Financial Markets Regulation. Regulatory Policy Research Centre, Hertford College, University of Oxford, September 12–14.Google Scholar
  5. London Stock Exchange. (1994a). “Guidance on the Dissemination of Price Sensitive Information.” February.Google Scholar
  6. London Stock Exchange. (1994b). “Orderly Markets: Dealings Ahead of the Disclosure of Price-Sensitive Information. October.Google Scholar
  7. Holland, J. and G. Stoner. (1995). “Corporate Problems with the Identification and Dissemination of Price-Sensitive Information.” BAA conference, Bristol, April (and University of Glasgow working paper).Google Scholar
  8. Hopwood, A. (1983). “On Trying to Study Accountancy in the Contexts in Which It Operates.”Accounting Organisations and Society 8, 287–305.Google Scholar
  9. Keenan. D. (1993). “New Rules for Insider Dealing.”Accountancy (December), 139.Google Scholar
  10. Kester, W. Carl. (1992). “Governance, Contracting, and Investment Horizons: A Look at Japan and Germany.”Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 5, (2) (Summer), 83–98.Google Scholar
  11. Large, A. (1994). “SIB Seeks Big Increase in Powers.”Independent, March 8, p. 25.Google Scholar
  12. Loomis, p. (1972). “Loomis on Inside Information.”Financial Analysts Journal 28(3) (May–June), 20–25. pp 82–88.Google Scholar
  13. Manne, R. (1966).Insider Trading and the Stock Market. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
  14. Pozen, R. C. (1994). “Institutional Investors: The Reluctant Activists.”Harvard Business Review (January–February), 140–149.Google Scholar
  15. Rice, R. (1994). “Analysts Wary of Tighter Net.”Financial Times, March 22, p. 16.Google Scholar
  16. Rider, B. C. Abrams and E. Ferran. (1989).Guide to the Financial Services Act 1986 (2nd ed.) Bicester, Oxfordshire, UK: CCH Editions Ltd.Google Scholar
  17. Shackle, G. L. S. (1970).Expectation, Enterprise and Profit. London: George Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
  18. Schmidt, H. (1991). “Insider Regulation and Economic Theory.”European Insider Dealing, (ch. 2). London: Butterworths.Google Scholar
  19. Scott, J. (1993). “Corporate Groups and Network Structures.” In J. McCahery, S. Picciotto, and C. Scott,Corporate Control and Accountability (ch. 16). Oxford Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
  20. Stephen, Frank. (1986). “Decision Making Under Uncertainty: In Defence of Shackle.”Journal of Economic Studies 13(5), 45–57.Google Scholar
  21. Scapens, R. W. (1990). “Researching Management Accounting Practice: The Role of Case Study Methods.”British Accounting Review 22, 259–281.Google Scholar
  22. Seyhun, H. N. (1992). “The Effectiveness of the Insider Trading Sanctions.”Journal of Law and Economics 35 April 1992, p 149–182.Google Scholar
  23. Shefrin, H., and M. Statman. (1993). “Ethics, Fairness and Efficiency in Financial Markets.”Financial Analysts Journal (November–December), 21–29.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Kluwer Academic Publishers 1996

Authors and Affiliations

  • John Holland
    • 1
  1. 1.Department of Accounting and FinanceUniversity of GlasgowGlasgowScotland, U.K.

Personalised recommendations