Skip to main content
Log in

Elections and aggregation: Interpreting econometric analyses of local governments

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Conclusion

This paper analyzes the provision of local government service under the assumption that fiscal policy is set by local officials in order to maximize the expected number of votes in the next election. The model includes both the widely-used median voter model and the “average voter” model as special cases. Further, it is a convenient framework for empirical analyses.

Numerical simulations indicate that the vote-maximization model is capable of producing levels of government spending either greater or less than those predicted by the median voter model, while exhibiting similar responses to changes in incomes, grants, prices, etc.. Thus, the model captures the advantages of the median voter model without its objectionable features.

Many avenues for further work remain, I will mention briefly only a few of the most obvious. The first is to make housing prices endogenously determined within the model. In this way, one could examine the role of both fiscal incentives (capitalization) and political incentives (votes) in the determination of optimal policies.

A second extension is to introduce explicitly the possibility of a mobile population and examine, in the spirit of Tiebout (1956), the effects of “voting with your feet” within the vote-maximization framework. The possibilities include both setting policies that de facto concede exit of some fraction of the current residents and/or setting policies to attract new residents with particular characteristics.

Another extension is to look at decisions over time. Despite widespread agreement upon the usefulness of the life-cycle model of private consumption, the median voter is essentially static. It seems a minimal extension to include both government and private consumption in an intertemporal framework. Unfortunately, the median voter may change over time, making implementation of the median voter model problematic at best.

In practice, intertemporal issues are important, emphasizing the absence of an acceptable framework. It is often suggested that elected officials will choose inappropriate intertemporal fiscal policies in response to the short-run focus of the electoral process. For example, it appears plausible that officials will borrow in order to finance higher levels of spending (and/or lower taxes) in the present. Because future residents are not present to vote against these policies, the electoral process produces incorrect incentives. In the same way, this line of reasoning suggests that officials will undertake too little infrastructure investments because the benefits accrue to future residents. One countervailing force is the effects of property capitalization. To the extent that the local housing market correctly capitalizes future taxes and services into housing values, current residents will be affected by inefficient policies and may use the electoral process to provide correct signals to officials.

There is another possibility as well. To the extent that current officials recognize that inefficient current policies reduce the probability of future re-election, they have an incentive — even in the absence of perfect capitalization — to adopt intertemporally appropriate tax and spending policies. Intuitively, the official must care about re-election. What if the particular individual chooses not to run for office again? Then, to the extent that political parties or machines cause the individual to value the election of his successor; i.e., to the extent that political “legacies” are important, the adopted policies may satisfy the conditions for intertemporal efficiency. The vote-maximization approach provides a framework in which to analyze these issues.

Lastly, one could extend the model to situations in which officials care not only about election, but also about the policies themselves. This provides not only a different tradeoff between the tastes of the public and private sector, but also a natural incentive for officials to seek re-election.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations (ACIR). (1986). Significant features of fiscal federalism 1985–86. Washington: United States Government Printing Office.

    Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson, A. and Stern, N. (1974). Pigou, taxation and public goods. Review of Economic Studies 41: 119–128.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bergstrom, T. and Goodman, R. (1973). Private demands for public goods. American Economic Review 63 (June): 280–296.

    Google Scholar 

  • Borcherding, T. and Deacon, R. (1972). The demand for the services of non-federal governments. American Economic Review 62: 891–901.

    Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957) An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper and Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edwards, J. (1985). Congestion function specification and the publicness of local public goods. Unpublished. Tulane University.

  • Feldstein, M. and Metcalf, G. (1987). The effect of federal tax deductibility on state and local taxes and spending. Journal of Political Economy 95 (August): 710–736.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, R. and Slemrod, J. (1986). An examination of municipal financial policy. In H. Rosen (Ed.), Studies in state and local public finance, 53–78. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gramlich, E. (1985). The deductibility of state and local taxes. National Tax Journal 38 (December): 447–466.

    Google Scholar 

  • Groves, T. and Todo-Rovira, A. (1986). The theory and estimation of demand for local public goods: An alternative to the median voter model. Mimeo. University of California, San Diego. October.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, B. (1983). The flypaper effect and other anomalies. Journal of Public Economic 22: 347–361.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hinich, M. (1977). Equilibrium in spatial voting: The median voter result is an artifact. Journal of Economic Theory 16: 208–219.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holtz-Eakin, D. and Rosen, H. (1988). Tax deductibility and municipal budget structure. In H. Rosen (Ed.), Fiscal federalism: Quantitative studies, 107–126. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holtz-Eakin, D. and Rosen, H. (1990). Federal deductibility and local property tax rates. Journal of Urban Economics 27.3 (May): 269–284.

    Google Scholar 

  • Inman, R. (1988). Markets, Governments, and the ‘new’ political economy. In M. Feldstein and A. Auerbach (Eds.), Handbook of public economics, Vol. 2, 647–777. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Inman, R. (1989). The local decision to tax: Evidence from large U.S. cities. Regional Science and Urban Economics 19.3 (August): 455–492.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindsey, L. (1988). Federal deductibility of state and local taxes: A test of public choice by representative government. In H. Rosen (Ed.), Fiscal federalism: Quantitative studies, 137–175. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Noto, N. and Zimmerman, D. (1984). Limiting state-local tax deductibility: Effects among the states. National Tax Journal 37 (December): 539–550.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oates, W. (1986). The estimation of demand functions for local public goods: Issues in specification and interpretation. Mimeo. University of Maryland, October.

  • Pechman, J. (1985). Who paid the taxes, 1966–85? Place: The Brookings Institution.

    Google Scholar 

  • Plott, C. (1967). A notion of equilibrium and its possibility under majority rule. American Economic Review, 788–806.

  • Romer, T. and Rosenthal, H. (1979). Bureaucrats vs voters: On the political economy of resource allocation by direct democracy. Quarterly Journal of Economics 93 (November): 563–587.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, T. and Rosenthal, H. (1979). The elusive median voter. Journal of Public Economics 12: 143–170.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schwab, R. and Zampelli, E. (1986). Disentangling the demand function from the production function for local public services: The case of public safety. Mimeo. University of Maryland, April.

  • Schwartz, A. Individual production and the provision of public services: Theory. Mimeo. Columbia University.

  • Stoker, T. (1986). Simple tests of distributional effects on macroeconomic equations. Journal of Political Economy 94 (August): 763–795.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. and Dasgupta, P. (1971). Differential taxation, public goods, and economic efficiency. Review of Economic Studies 38: 151–174.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tiebout, C. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditure. Journal of Political Economy 64: 416–424.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tresch, R. (1981). Public finance: A normative theory, Plano: Business Publications, Inc..

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Additional information

I thank Cynthia Miller for superb research assistance. I have benefitted from excellent comments by Rosanne Altshuler, Douglas Blair, Chris Grandy, Leo Kahane, Cynthia Miller, Brendan O'Flaherty, Harvey Rosen, Max Sawicky, Amy Ellen Schwartz and members of workshops at Columbia University and Rutgers University. I thank Esther Gray for superb secretarial assistance. A previous version of this paper circulated under the title “Vote Maximization and the Provision of Local Government Services”.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Holtz-Eakin, D. Elections and aggregation: Interpreting econometric analyses of local governments. Public Choice 74, 17–42 (1992). https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00175209

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00175209

Keywords

Navigation