Skip to main content
Log in

Incumbency effects in political campaigns

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper we examine two effects of incumbency. First, an incumbent may have an advantage in creating a favorable image in the eyes of the voters. Second, the incumbent may have to chose a position before the challenger; this second aspect of incumbency is modelled as Stackelberg leadership. In the model two candidates run for election by choosing a position in an ideological spectrum. Voters care about candidates' chosen positions as well as non-policy attributes of candidates, which we call charisma. Charismata are not known when candidates choose policy positions; they are only revealed on election day so that winning is not usually a certain prospect. Candidates care about the probability of winning but they also dislike compromising their own ideals.

We find that the incumbent's equilibrium position is closer to his/her own ideal point than the equilibrium position of the game when moves are simultaneous. Also, for sufficiently large charismatic differences a natural leadership regime prevails: the candidate with the large charismatic advantage prefers being a leader to being a follower and the opponent prefers being a follower. If the difference in charismata is small both players prefer to be followers

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Austen-Smith, D. (1987). Interest groups, campaign contributions, and pluralistic voting. Public Choice 54: 123–137.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernhardt, M.D. and Ingberman, D.E. (1985). Candidate reputations and the ‘incumbency effect’. Journal of Public Economics 27: 47–67.

    Google Scholar 

  • Born, R. (1979). Generational replacement and the growth of incumbent safety margins in the U.S. House. American Political Science Review 73: 811–817.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caplin, A. and Nalebuff, B. (1988). On 64% majority rule. Econometrica 56: 787–814.

    Google Scholar 

  • Collie, M.P. (1981). Incumbency, electoral safety, and turnover in the House of Representatives. American Political Science Review 75: 119–131.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coughlin, P.J. (1990). Candidate uncertainty and electoral equilibria. In J.M. Enelow and M.J. Hinich (Eds.), Advances in the spatial theory of voting. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cox, G.W. (1984). An expected-utility model of electoral competition. Quality and Quantity 18: 337–349.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edelman, S.A. (1990). Two politicians, a PAC, and how they interact: Two sequential models. Mimeo. Columbia University, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Enelow, J.M. (1990). An expanded approach to analyzing policy-minded candidates. Mimeo. University of Texas at Austin.

  • Enelow, J.M. and Hinich, M.J. (1984). The spatial theory of voting. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fiorina, M.P. (1977). Congress — Keystone of the Washington establishment. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garand, J.C. and Gross, D.A. (1984). Changes in the vote margins for congressional candidates: A specification of historical trends. American Political Science Review 78: 17–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansson, I. and Stuart, Ch. (1984). Voting competitions with interested politicians: Platforms do not converge to the preferences of the median voter. Public Choice 44: 431–441.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell, D.W. (1987). Candidate behavior under mixed motives. Social Choice and Welfare 4: 153–160.

    Google Scholar 

  • Palfrey, T.R. (1984). Spatial equilibrium with entry. Review of Economic Studies 51: 139–156.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, L. (1984). Electoral equilibria with restricted strategies. Public Choice 43: 307–327.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, L. (1987). A test of the revealed-preference phenomenon in congressional elections. Public Choice 54: 141–169.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wittman, D. (1990). Spatial strategies when candidates have policy preferences. In J.M. Enelow and M.J. Hinich (Eds.), Advances in the spatial theory of voting. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Additional information

This is a revised version of Thomas Jefferson Discussion Paper 199. We are grateful to participants of the Public Economics Workshop at the University of Virginia and to an anonymous referee for helpful comments on earlier versions of this paper. John Chilton and Doug Mitchell have also given us exceptionally fine detailed suggestions for improvements. The usual caveat applies.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Anderson, S.P., Glomm, G. Incumbency effects in political campaigns. Public Choice 74, 207–219 (1992). https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00140768

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00140768

Keywords

Navigation