Skip to main content
Log in

Agenda control by budget maximizers in a multi-bureau setting

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Concluding remarks

While the present extension of the single issue model of agenda control has permitted the examination of a wide array of questions within a consistent overall framework and has generated new insights, some qualifications are in order. First, the analysis, like Niskanen's and Romer and Rosenthal's is strictly limited to one form of agenda control — take-it-or-leave-it offers made relative to some reversion level. Second, each of the bureaus in this extension are single activity bureaus. As a result, certain types of agenda control that might exist when there are several dimensions to each bureau's activity, such as the mix chosen for various sub-activities or the spatial distribution of the bureau's output, are ignored.Footnote 1 Third, as a point of reference and for expositional simplicity, the analysis for the most part was executed with a single decisive voter on all issues. As a result, certain complexities and, perhaps, additional ambiguities were avoided.

Finally, in an effort to isolate and study the effects of the supply side phenomenon of agenda control, a simple, traditional model of the demand side of the collective choice process was employed. For the simplest demand side-passive supply side models this has typically proved quite adequate. As models of the collective choice process have become more complex, however, taking on more strategic features, the weaknesses of certain of the standard assumptions implicit in this demand side model become more apparent. In particular, the assumption that voters vote sincerely and non-strategically is likely to be strained by most specifications of the dynamics of the voting process since learning on the part of voters would condition expectations and, perhaps, alter choice. The inclusion of expectations formation into the model of voter behavior would certainly seem, at least at the intuitive level, to introduce an interesting additional set of constraints on agenda setters that may limit to some extent the expansionary tendencies described in this paper. In short, each of these qualifications should provide fertile ground for future research.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Denzau and Mackay (1980) and Mackay and Weaver (1979a, b) for analyses of these types of agenda control for the case of a single bureau.

References

  • Barr, J., and Davis, O. (1966). An elementary political and economic theory of the expenditures of local governments.Southern Economic Journal 333 (October).

  • Bergstrom, T., and Goodman R. (1973). Private demands for public goods.American Economic Review 63 (March): 280–296.

    Google Scholar 

  • Black, D. (1958).The theory of committees and elections. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Black, D., and Newing, R. A. (1951).Committee decisions with complementary valuation. London: William Hodge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Borcherding, T., and Deacon, R. (1972). The demand for the services of non-federal governments.American Economic Review 62 (December): 891–901.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowen, H. (1943). The interpretation of voting in the allocation of economic resources.Quarterly Journal of Economics 58 (November): 27–48.

    Google Scholar 

  • Browning, E. (1975). Collective choice and general fund financing.Journal of Political Economy 83 (April): 377–390.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1963). The economics of earmarked taxes.The Journal of Political Economy 71 (October): 457–469.

    Google Scholar 

  • Calhoun, L., Hinich, M., and Ordeshook, P. (1978). A statistical multi-dimensional scaling method based on the spatial theory of voting. In P. Wang (Ed.),Graphical representation of multi-variate data. Academic Press.

  • Davis, O., and Hinich, M. (1966). A mathematical model of policy formation in a democratic society. In J. L. Bernd (Ed.),Mathematical applications in political science II. Dallas: SMU Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, O., Hinich, M., and Ordeshook, P. (1970). An expository development of a mathematical model of the electoral process.American Political Science Review 64 (June): 426–448.

    Google Scholar 

  • Denzau, A., and Mackay, R. (1978). Expectations in sequential elections. Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University. Mimeo.

  • Denzau, A., and Mackay, R. (1980). Benefit and tax share discrimination by a monopoly bureau.Journal of Public Economics 13: 341–368.

    Google Scholar 

  • Denzau, A., and Mackay, R. (1981). Structure induced equilibria and perfect foresight expectations.American Journal of Political Science. Forthcoming.

  • Denzau, A., Mackay, R., and Weaver, C. (1979a). The possibility of majority rule equilibrium with agenda costs. Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University. Mimeo.

  • Denzau, A., Mackay, R., and Weaver, C. (1979b). Structured induced equilibria, earmarking and general fund financing. Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University. Mimeo.

  • Denzau, A., and Parks, R. (1977). A problem with public sector preferences.Journal of Economic Theory 14(April): 454–457.

    Google Scholar 

  • Denzau, A., and Parks, R. (1979). Deriving public sector preferences.Journal of Public Economics 11(June): 335–352.

    Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957).An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper and Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hinich, M., and Mackay, R. (1979). On the determination of spending limitations and budgetary ceilings when voters' perception of the budgetary mix differ. Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University. Mimeo.

  • Hinich, M., and Pollard, W. (1979). A new approach to the spatial theory of electoral competition.American Journal of Political Science. Forthcoming.

  • Hoffman, E., and Packel, E. (1979). A theoretical approach to the decision to stop deliberating over legislative alternatives. Center for Mathematical Studies in Economics and Management Science, Northwestern University, May. Mimeo.

  • Hoyer, R., and Mayer, L. (1974). Comparing strategies in a spatial model of electoral competition.American Journal of Political Science 18(August): 501–523.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kadane, J. (1972). On division of the question.Public Choice 13(Fall): 47–54.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kramer, G. (1972). Sophisticated voting over multi-dimensional choice spaces.Journal of Mathematical Sociology 2(July): 165–181.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mackay, R., and Weaver, C. (1978a). Monopoly bureaus and fiscal outcomes. In G. Tullock and R. Wagner (Eds.),Deductive Reasoning in the Analysis of Public Policy. Lexington.

  • Mackay, R., and Weaver, C. (1978b). Monopoly and commodity bundling in public supply: A diagrammatic exposition. Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University. Mimeo.

  • Mackay, R., and Weaver, C. (1979a). On the mutuality of interests between bureaus and high demand review committees.Public Choice 34(3–4): 481–491.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mackay, R., and Weaver, C. (1979b). Commodity bundling and agenda control in the public sector: A mathematical analysis. Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University. Mimeo.

  • Mackay, R., and Whitney, G. (1980). The comparative statics of quantity constraints on conditional demands: Theory and applications.Econometrica 48(November): 1727–1744.

    Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey, R. (1976). Intransitivities in multi-dimensional voting models and some implications for agenda control.Journal of Economic Theory 12: 472–482.

    Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey, R. (1977). General conditions for global informal voting models: Some implications for agenda control. SUPA, Carnegie-Mellon University. Mimeo.

  • Niskanen, W. (1968). The feculiar economics of bureaucracy.American Economic Review 58 (May): 293–305.

    Google Scholar 

  • Niskanen, W. (1971).Bureaucracy and representative government. Chicago: Aldine-Atherton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Plott, C. (1967). A notion of equilibrium and its possibility under majority rule.American Economic Review 157 (September): 787–806.

    Google Scholar 

  • Plott, C., and Levine, M. (1978). A model of agenda influence on committee decisions.American Economic Review 68 (March): 146–160.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rabinowitz, G. (1974).Spatial models of electoral choice. Social Science Monograph: University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill.

  • Riker, W., and Ordeshook, P. (1973).An introduction to positive political theory. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, T., and Rosenthal, H. (1978). Political resource allocation, controlled agenda, and the status quo.Public Choice 33(4): 27–43.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, T., and Rosenthal, H. (1979a). Bureaucrats v. voters: On the political economy of resource allocation by direct democracy.Quarterly Journal of Economics 93.

  • Romer, T., and Rosenthal, H. (1979b). The elusive median voter.Journal of Public Economics 2 (October).

  • Romer, T., and Rosenthal, H. (1980). Setters, reversions and median voters: Evidence from school expenditure referenda. Carnegie-Mellon University. Mimeo.

  • Schofield, N. (1978). Instability of simple dynamic games.Review of Economic Studies 45: 575–594.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle, K. (1979). Institutional arrangements and equilibrium in multi-dimensional voting models.American Journal of Political Science 23(February): 27–59.

    Google Scholar 

  • Slutsky, S. (1977). A voting model for the allocation of public goods: Existence of an equilibrium.Journal of Economic Theory 14 (April): 299–325.

    Google Scholar 

  • Slutsky, S. (1977). Restricted voting equilibria in multi-dimensional spaces. Cornell University. Mimeo.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Additional information

The research for this paper was supported in part by the National Science Foundation under Grants SOC 76-22438 and SOC 79-08561.

We would like to thank James M. Buchanan, Richard E. Wagner and participants in the Public Choice Seminar, Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University, and the Department of Economics Seminar, University of Iowa, for their helpful comments on the first draft of this paper.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Mackay, R.J., Weaver, C.L. Agenda control by budget maximizers in a multi-bureau setting. Public Choice 37, 447–472 (1981). https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00133745

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00133745

Keywords

Navigation