Advertisement

Public Choice

, Volume 64, Issue 1, pp 21–41 | Cite as

Susceptibility to manipulation

  • Donald G. Saari
Article

Abstract

All positional voting procedures can be manipulated, so it is natural to question whether some of these systems are more susceptible to being manipulated than others. In this essay, this susceptibility factor is measured for strategic action involving small groups. It is shown that the system least susceptible to micro manipulations for n = 3 candidates is the Borda Count (BC). The optimal choice changes with n, but the analysis shows that the BC always fares fairly well. On the other hand, the plurality and anti-plurality vote as well as multiple voting systems, such as approval voting and cumulative voting, always fare quite poorly with respect to susceptibility. Finally, it is shown why it is possible to justify any voting method by choosing an appropriate measure of susceptibility and imposing the appropriate assumptions on the profiles of voters. This statement emphasizes the importance of the basic assumptions of neutrality used throughout this essay.

Keywords

Small Group Public Finance Basic Assumption Optimal Choice Vote System 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Brams, S. and Fishburn, P. (1984). Manipulability of voting by sincere truncation of preferences. Public Choice 44: 397–410.Google Scholar
  2. Chamberlin, J. (1985). Investigation into the relative manipulability of four voting systems. Behavioral Science 30: 195–203.Google Scholar
  3. Gibbard, A. (1973). Manipulation of voting schemes: A general result. Econometrica 41: 587–602.Google Scholar
  4. Meyerson, R. (1988). Mechanism design. In J. Eatwell, Milgate and P. Newman (Eds.), Allocation, information, and markets.Google Scholar
  5. Niemi, R. (1984). The problem of strategic behavior under approval voting. American Political Science Review 78: 952–958.Google Scholar
  6. Nitzan, S. (1985). The vulnerability of point-voting schemes to preference variation and strategic manipulation. Public Choice 47: 349–370.Google Scholar
  7. Riker, W.H. (1982). Liberalism against populism. San Francisco: W.H. Freeman.Google Scholar
  8. Saari, D.G. (1989a). A dictionary for voting paradoxes. Journal of Economic Theory.Google Scholar
  9. Saari, D.G. (1989b). The Borda dictionary. NU Center for Mathematical Economics, Discussion paper #821, Northwestern University, Evanston, IL.Google Scholar
  10. Saari, D.G. and van Newenhizen, J. (1988a). The problem of indeterminancy in approval, multiple, and truncated voting systems. Public Choice 59: 101–120.Google Scholar
  11. Saari, D.G. and van Newenhizen, J. (1988b). Is approval voting an ‘unmitigated evil’: A response to Brams, Fishburn, and Merrill. Public Choice 59: 133–147.Google Scholar
  12. Satterthwaite, M. (1975). Strategy-proofness and Arrow's conditions: Existence and correspondence theorem for voting procedures and social welfare functions. Journal of Economic Theory 10: 187–217.Google Scholar
  13. Sawyer and MacRae (1962). Game theory and cumulative voting in Illinois: 1902–1954. American Political Science Review 56: 936–946.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Kluwer Academic Publishers 1990

Authors and Affiliations

  • Donald G. Saari
    • 1
  1. 1.Department of Mathematics, Lunt HallNorthwestern UniversityEvanston

Personalised recommendations