Skip to main content
Log in

Susceptibility to manipulation

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

All positional voting procedures can be manipulated, so it is natural to question whether some of these systems are more susceptible to being manipulated than others. In this essay, this susceptibility factor is measured for strategic action involving small groups. It is shown that the system least susceptible to micro manipulations for n = 3 candidates is the Borda Count (BC). The optimal choice changes with n, but the analysis shows that the BC always fares fairly well. On the other hand, the plurality and anti-plurality vote as well as multiple voting systems, such as approval voting and cumulative voting, always fare quite poorly with respect to susceptibility. Finally, it is shown why it is possible to justify any voting method by choosing an appropriate measure of susceptibility and imposing the appropriate assumptions on the profiles of voters. This statement emphasizes the importance of the basic assumptions of neutrality used throughout this essay.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Brams, S. and Fishburn, P. (1984). Manipulability of voting by sincere truncation of preferences. Public Choice 44: 397–410.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chamberlin, J. (1985). Investigation into the relative manipulability of four voting systems. Behavioral Science 30: 195–203.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gibbard, A. (1973). Manipulation of voting schemes: A general result. Econometrica 41: 587–602.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meyerson, R. (1988). Mechanism design. In J. Eatwell, Milgate and P. Newman (Eds.), Allocation, information, and markets.

  • Niemi, R. (1984). The problem of strategic behavior under approval voting. American Political Science Review 78: 952–958.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nitzan, S. (1985). The vulnerability of point-voting schemes to preference variation and strategic manipulation. Public Choice 47: 349–370.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W.H. (1982). Liberalism against populism. San Francisco: W.H. Freeman.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saari, D.G. (1989a). A dictionary for voting paradoxes. Journal of Economic Theory.

  • Saari, D.G. (1989b). The Borda dictionary. NU Center for Mathematical Economics, Discussion paper #821, Northwestern University, Evanston, IL.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saari, D.G. and van Newenhizen, J. (1988a). The problem of indeterminancy in approval, multiple, and truncated voting systems. Public Choice 59: 101–120.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saari, D.G. and van Newenhizen, J. (1988b). Is approval voting an ‘unmitigated evil’: A response to Brams, Fishburn, and Merrill. Public Choice 59: 133–147.

    Google Scholar 

  • Satterthwaite, M. (1975). Strategy-proofness and Arrow's conditions: Existence and correspondence theorem for voting procedures and social welfare functions. Journal of Economic Theory 10: 187–217.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sawyer and MacRae (1962). Game theory and cumulative voting in Illinois: 1902–1954. American Political Science Review 56: 936–946.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Additional information

This research was supported, in part, by NSF grants IRI-8415348, IRI-8803505, and a Fellowship from the Guggenheim Memorial Foundation. Also, I would like to thank P. Aranson for his several helpful comments.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Saari, D.G. Susceptibility to manipulation. Public Choice 64, 21–41 (1990). https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00125915

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00125915

Keywords

Navigation