Skip to main content
Log in

The congressional-bureaucratic system: a principal agent perspective (with applications to the SEC)

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Conclusion

This paper provides the theoretical perspective and empirical support for congressional dominance of agency decisions. My thesis is twofold. First, because much of the previous evidence on this question is not evidence at all, many scholars' intuition and conclusions are based on a logically flawed foundation. Second, I have provided here and in previous work a look at a variety of different agencies, and in each case, have shown how the events can plausibly be interpreted as involving Congress. Agency problems within the congressional-bureaucratic system are real and substantial just as they are within corporations. However, as in the latter, institutional forms develop within the congressional system to partially, if not wholly, mitigate these problems. The logical perspective together with the evidence provide a strong case against the agency-dominance hypothesis (as typified by the early sections of Niskanen 1971 and Wilson 1980).

Reelection-minded congressmen have substantial incentives to ensure that agencies provide benefits to their constituents. The congressional-bureaucratic system does just that. Agencies are beholden to a small number of congressmen sitting on the relevant oversight committees. These congressmen evaluate agency performance through the decibel meter, i.e., through listening to their constituents, not through in-depth study. And finally, the congressional-bureaucratic system confronts agencies with powerful incentives to serve congressional — read committee — interests. Political scientist Morris Fiorina sums up this approach as follows:

qu]The federal agencies exist in a symbiotic relationship with the congressional committees and subcommittees to which they report. Of course, not everything an agency does is of concern to its set of relevant members. It purchases freedom in such areas by playing ball in the areas that are of concern. So part of the agency may be genuinely out of control, but Congress wants it that way. It is a necessary cost of maintaining a bureaucracy ... permeable to congressional influence. (Fiorina 1982b, p. 337, emphasis in original)

Several tentative generalizations for deregulation emerge from this perspective. (1) Policy change requires that congressmen perceive political net benefits from the change. If this involves a change in constitutencies, then members of the relevant committees must be willing to give up their current constitutents. For the SEC, the rise of the institutional investors provided such an opportunity. For the ICC and the CAB, the political credit to be gained from deregulation is less obvious and provides a major unresolved issue in the economic theory of regulation.

(2) “Market testing,” as undertaken by the SEC, is probably a regular component of the congressional-bureaucratic system. A congressional committee allows an agency to test the waters and generate information about the political effects of a policy change. If the policy change appears politically successful, then Congress provides a statutory underpinning, perhaps extending significantly the scope of the experiment. If it is unsuccessful, then Congress moves to reinstate the status quo. Clearly, there were significant elements of this in the case of the CAB. Congress allowed deregulation-minded economists and lawyers (e.g., Kahn, Bailey, Levine) to take control of the Board. To their credit, these individuals were able to initiate rate deregulation within existing legislation. This proved so successful that, though the final legislation in 1978 significantly extended the bounds of deregulation, it seemed but icing on the cake.

(3) The above perspective points up the role of Congress in maintaining policy equilibrium. As the history of the SEC demonstrates, we must examine events preceding the deregulatory period. The evidence reveals that plausible hypotheses about SEC policy change make little sense when studied in the context of thirty-years worth of Commission activity. Similarly, an explanation of CAB or ICC deregulation must not only explain why it occurred in the late 1970s but also why it failed to occur during the previous thirty years. Every president during this period tested the waters of, or actively sought, transportation reform. Yet, prior to the late 1970s, none was successful because the relevant committees rebuffed these efforts.

(4) Finally, while marginal accommodations to changes in group composition (to paraphrase Mackay and Reid, 1979) occur within the congressional system, policy remains stable as long as the relevant groups remain stable. This implies that for the near future, substantial progress toward reform or deregulation is unlikely for most social regulatory agencies.

This paper suggests the necessary role of Congress in the regulatory policymaking system. Regulatory change, whether halting FTC activism or deregulation as undertaken by the SEC, constitutes a change within the congressional system. While I have argued an extreme view — namely, that Congress is of supreme importance — the evidence is consistent with it. But this view is used primarily to show that the other extreme — agency dominance — seems clearly inconsistent with the evidence. Whether the congressional-dominance hypothesis or a more moderate “shared-influence hypothesis” is more descriptively accurate is not my concern here. Rather, my fundamental premise is that the assumption that Congress controls regulation will prove as useful in understanding regulatory behavior as the assumption that firms maximize profits has proved to be in economic analysis of market behavior.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Alchian, A. (1950) Uncertainty, Evolution, and Economic Theory, Journal of Political Economy, 58: 211–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • and Demsetz, H. (1972) Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization, American Economic Review, 62: 777–95.

    Google Scholar 

  • Armstrong, J. (1959) Congress and the Securities and Exchange Commission, Virginia Law Review, 45: 795–816.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barke, R. and Riker, W. (1982) A Political Theory of Regulation with Some Observations on Railway Abandonments, Carnegie Papers on Political Economy, Public Choice, 39: 73–106.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baxter, W. (1970) NYSE Fixed Commission Rates, Stanford Law Review, 22: 675–712.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benston, G. (1973) Required Disclosure and the Stock Market, American Economic Review, 63: 132–55.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cary, W. (1967) Politics and the Regulatory Commissions. New York: McGraw Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clarkson, K. (1981) Legislative Constraints. In Clarkson and Muris (1981).

  • Clarkson, K. and Muris, T. (1981) (Eds.) The Federal Trade Commission Since 1970. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (1969) Perfect Competition, Regulation, and the Stock Market, (ed.) H. Manne, Economic Policy and the Regulation of Corporate Securities. Washington: American Enterprise Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • (1982) Economic, Political and Legal Dimensions of Competition. Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Denzau, A. and Mackay, R. (1983) Gate Keeping and Monopoly Power of Committees, American Journal of Political Science, 27: 740–61.

    Google Scholar 

  • Denzau, A., Mackay, R., and Weaver, C. (1979) Spending Limitations, Agenda Control and Voters' Expectations. National Tax Journal (Supplement) 32: 189–209.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. and Jensen, M. (1983a) Separation of Ownership and Control. Journal of Law and Economics, 26: 301–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • and (1983b) Agency Problems and Residual Claims. Journal of Law and Economics, 26: 327–50.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fenno, R. (1973) Congressmen in Committees. Boston: Little Brown.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fiorina, M. (1974) Representatives, Constituencies, and Roll Calls. Lexington: Lexington Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fiorina, M. (1977) Congress: Keystone of the Washington Establishment. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • (1982a) Legislative Choice of Regulatory Forms. Carnegie Papers on Political Economy, Public Choice, 39: 33–66.

    Google Scholar 

  • (1982b) Congressional Control of the Bureaucracy. (Eds.) L. Dodd and B. Oppenheimer, Congress Reconsidered, 2 ed. Washington: CQ Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmstrom, B., (1979) Moral Hazard and Observability. Bell Journal of Economics, 10: 74–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jarrell, G. (1983) Change at the Exchange. Journal of Law and Economics (forthcoming).

  • Jensen, M. and Meckling, W. (1976) The Theory of the Firm. Journal of Financial Economics, 3: 305–60.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kohlmeier, L. (1969) The Regulators. New York: Harper and Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krasnow, E. et al. (1982) The Politics of Broadcast Regulation. New York: St. Martin's.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kripke, H. (1970) The SEC, the Accountant, Some Myths, and Some Realities. The New York University Law Review, 45: 1151.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mackay, R. and Reid, J. (1979) Understanding the Birth and Evolution of the Securities and Exchange Commission, (ed.) G. Walton, Regulatory Change in an Atmosphere of Crisis. New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCubbins, M. and Schwartz, T. (1984) Congressional Oversight Overlooked. American Journal of Political Science, 28: 165–79.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mann, M. (1975) The New York Stock Exchange: A Cartel at the End of Its Reign, (ed.) A. Phillips, Promoting Competition in Regulated Markets. Washington: Brookings.

    Google Scholar 

  • Manne, H. (1974) Economic Aspects of Required Disclosure Under Federal Securities Laws, (eds.) H. Manne and E. Solomon, Wall Street in Transition. New York: New York University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mayhew, D. (1974) Congress: The Electoral Connection. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitnick, B. (1980) Political Economy of Regulation. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moran, M. (1983) Impairment or Corrective: Insider Trading and the Stock Market. Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation, Washington University.

  • Niskanen, W. (1972) Bureaucracy and Representative Government. Chicago: Aldine.

    Google Scholar 

  • Noll, R. (1971) Reforming Regulation. Washington: Brookings.

    Google Scholar 

  • Noll, R. (1976) Governmental Administrative Behavior, Social Science Working Paper No. 62: California Institute of Technology.

  • Noll, R. and Peck, M., and MacGowan (1974) Economics of Television Regulation. Washington: Brookings.

    Google Scholar 

  • and Owen, B. (1983) Political Economy of Deregulation. Washington: American Economic Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ogul, M. (1976) Congress Oversees the Bureaucracy. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, S. (1976) Toward a More General Theory of Regulation. Journal of Law and Economics, 19: 211–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Phillips, S. and Zecher, R. (1981) The SEC and the Public Interest. Cambridge: Massachusetts Institute of Technology Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, T. and Rosenthal, H. (1978) Political Resource Allocation, Controlled Agendas, and the Status Quo. Public Choice, 33: 27–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schwert, G. (1977) Public Regulation of National Securities Exchanges, Bell Journal of Economics, 8: 128–50.

    Google Scholar 

  • Seligman, J. (1982) The Transformation of Wall Street. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle, K. (1978) The Giant Jigsaw Puzzle. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • and Weingast, B. (1981) Structure Induced Equilibrium and Legislative Choice. Public Choice, 37: 503–20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. (1964) Public Regulation of the Securities Market, Journal of Business, 17: 117–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • (1971) The Economic Theory of Regulation, Bell Journal of Economics, 2: 3–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stoll, H. (1981) Revolution in the Regulation of Securities Markets, (eds.) L. Weiss and M. Klass, Case Studies in Regulation. Boston: Little Brown.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tinic, S. and West, R. (1980) The Securities Industry Under Negotiated Brokerage Commissions. Bell Journal of Economics, 11: 29–41.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1965) The Politics of Bureaucracy. Washington, D.C.: Public Affairs Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. (1977) A Representative Legislature and Regulatory Agency Capture. Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation, California Institute of Technology.

  • Weingast, B. (1981) Regulation, Reregulation, and Deregulation: The Foundations of Agency-Clientele Relations, Law and Contemporary Problems, 44: 147–77.

    Google Scholar 

  • (1984) The Industrial Organization of Congress. Mimeo., Center for the Study of American Business, Washington University, St. Louis.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. and Moran, M. (1983) Bureaucratic Discretion or Congressional Control: Regulatory Policymaking by the Federal Trade Commission. Journal of Political Economy, 91: 765–800.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. (1975) Markets and Hierarchies. New York: The Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, J. (1980) The Politics of Regulation. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Additional information

Associate professor of economics and business, and research associate at the Center for the Study of American Business, Washington University. I gratefully acknowledge helpful comments from James Alt, Lee Benham, Randall Calvert, Harold Demsetz, Arthur Denzau, Kenneth Lehn, Mark Moran, and Kenneth Shepsle. Research assistance was provided by David Tsadka. Partial support was provided by NSF Grant SES-8311691.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Weingast, B.R. The congressional-bureaucratic system: a principal agent perspective (with applications to the SEC). Public Choice 44, 147–191 (1984). https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00124821

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00124821

Keywords

Navigation