Advertisement

Journal of Industrial and Business Economics

, Volume 46, Issue 4, pp 459–498 | Cite as

Regulatory capture in the US petroleum refining industry

  • Robert GmeinerEmail author
Article
  • 23 Downloads

Abstract

The capture theory of regulation concludes that regulatory agencies tend to be captured by the firms they are regulating. This paper tests the capture theory in the recent environment of nuanced agency regulation by the administrative state, focusing on the US oil refining industry. Regulation has tended to narrow refiners’ margins, which harms nonintegrated oil refiners more than vertically integrated. Providing evidence of regulatory capture, complementary analysis of stock returns shows that regulations have benefited the stocks of vertically integrated firms. The narrowing of the margins is primarily due to rising input costs.

Keywords

Regulation Crack spreads Vertical integration Rent seeking 

JEL Classification

D72 K23 L71 

Notes

Compliance with ethical standards

Conflict of interest

On behalf of all authors, the corresponding author states that there is no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Al-Ubaydli, O., & McLaughlin, P. A. (2015). Regdata: A numerical database on industry-specific regulations for all United States industries and federal regulations, 1997–2012. Regulation and Governance, 11(1), 109–123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Becker, G. S. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98(3), 371–400.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Berman, E., & Bui, L. T. M. (2001). Environmental regulation and productivity: Evidence from oil refineries. Review of Economics and Statistics, 83(3), 498–510.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Borenstein, S., & Gilbert, R. (1993). Uncle sam at the gas pump: Causes and consequences of regulating gasoline distribution. Regulation, 16, 63–75.Google Scholar
  5. Boskin, M. J. (1993). Reflections on the Bush regulatory record. Regulation, 16, 22–35.Google Scholar
  6. Dorsey, L. G. (1995). Theodore Roosevelt and corporate America, 1901–1909: A reexamination. Presidential Studies Quarterly, 25(4), 725–739.Google Scholar
  7. Fama, E. (1970). Efficient capital markets: A review of theory and empirical work. Journal of Finance, 25(2), 383–417.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Gilens, M., & Page, B. I. (2014). Testing theories of American politics: Elites, interest groups, and average citizens. Perspectives on Politics, 12, 564–581.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Government Accountability Office. (2005). Superfund: Trends in federal funding and cleanup of epa’s nonfederal national priorities list sites.Google Scholar
  10. Gray, W. B. (1987). The cost of regulation: OSHA, EPA, and the productivity slowdown. American Economic Review, 77(5), 998–1006.Google Scholar
  11. Gray, W. B., Shadbegian R. J. (1995). Pollution abatement costs, regulation, and plant-level productivity. NBER Working Paper # 4994.Google Scholar
  12. Hastings, J. S., & Gilbert, R. J. (2005). Market power, vertical integration, and the wholesale price of gasoline. Journal of Industrial Economics, 53(4), 469–492.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Kalt, J. P. (1981). The Economics and Politics of Oil Price Regulation in the Post Embarge Era. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  14. Karikari, J. A., Godwin, A., Dezhbakhsh, H., & El-Osta, B. (2007). The impact of mergers in U.S. petroleum industry on wholesale gasoline prices. Contemporary Economic Policy, 25(1), 46–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Kendix, M., & Walls, W. (2010). Oil industry consolidation and refined product prices: Evidence from us wholesale gasoline terminals. Energy Policy, 38(7), 3498–3507.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Kolko, G. (1963). The Triumph of Conservatism; A Re-interpretation of American History, 1900–1916. New York: Free Press of Glencoe.Google Scholar
  17. Kwiatowski, D., Phillips, P. C., Schmidt, P., & Shin, Y. (1992). Testing the null hypothesis of stationarity against the alternative of a unit root: How sure are we that economic time series have a unit root? Journal of Econometrics, 54(1–3), 159–178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Liebeler, W. J. (1976). Integration and competition. In E. J. Mitchell (Ed.), Vertical Integration in the Oil Industry (pp. 9–14). Washington: American Enterprise Institute for Policy Research.Google Scholar
  19. Managi, S., Opaluch, J. T., Jin, D., & Grigalunas, T. A. (2005). Environmental regulations and technological change in the offshore oil and gas industry. Land Economics, 81(2), 303–319.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Mancke, R. (1976). Competition in the oil industry. In E. J. Mitchell (Ed.), Vertical Integration in the Oil Industry (pp. 35–72). Washington: American Enterprise Institute for Policy Research.Google Scholar
  21. Meiners, R . E., & Yandle, B. (1989). Regulatory lessons from the Reagan Era: Introduction. In R . E. Meiners & B. Yandle (Eds.), Regulation and the Reagan Era: Politics, Bureaucracy, and the Public Interest (pp. 3–15). New York: Holmes & Meier.Google Scholar
  22. Moe, R. C. (1994). The “reinventing government” exercise: Misinterpreting the problem, misjudging the consequences. Public Administration Review, 54(2), 111–122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Olson, M. (1971). The Logic of Collective Action. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  24. Owen, B. M., & Braeutigam, R. (1977). The Regulation Game: Strategic Use of the Administrative Process. Cambridge: Ballinger Publishing Company.Google Scholar
  25. Peltzman, S. (1976). Toward a more general theory of regulation. Journal of Law and Economics, 19(2), 211–240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Pesaran, H. H., & Shin, Y. (1998). Generalized impulse response analysis in linear multivariate models. Economics Letters, 58(1), 17–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Porter, M. E., & van der Linde, C. (1995). Toward a new conception of the environment–competitiveness relationship. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9(4), 97–118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Seelye, K. Q. (2005). Bush team is reversing environmental policies. New York Times.Google Scholar
  29. Simpson, J., & Taylor, C. (2008). Do gasoline mergers affect consumer prices? The Marathon Ashland petroleum and Ultramar diamond Shamrock transaction. Journal of Law and Economics, 51(1), 135–152.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Sims, C. A., Stock, J. H., & Watson, M. W. (1990). Inference in linear time series models with some unit roots. Econometrica, 58(1), 113–144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Stigler, G. J. (1971). The theory of economic regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2(1), 3–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Stiglitz, J. E. (2012). The Price of Inequality: How Today's Divided Society Endangers the Future. New York: Public Affairs Press.Google Scholar
  33. Wilson, W. (1887). The study of administration. Political Science Quarterly, 2(2), 197–222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Associazione Amici di Economia e Politica Industriale 2019

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Kennesaw State UniversityKennesawUSA

Personalised recommendations