Machinery production networks in Latin America: a quantity and quality analysis
Abstract
This paper investigates the effects that the increase in the importation of machinery parts and components and the changes in the supplier composition had in the trade of final products and parts and components inside Latin America. In our analysis, we consider these effects according to two dimensions: a quantity one that captures whether there was an intensification of trade and a quality one that captures changes in the sophistication of the traded goods. The research employs disaggregated trade data obtained from UN Comtrade for 17 Latin American countries between 1996 and 2011. We find evidence that an increase in the importation of parts and components from Latin America had positive impacts on both the quantity and quality dimensions. Subregional heterogeneities revealed that, in general, imports from East Asia had positive effects on the quantity dimension, nurturing the expansion of machinery production networks inside Latin America, and on the quality dimension, increasing the sophistication of the products traded inside Latin America, especially for Mercosur member exports. Imports from North America had positive quantity effects, especially for exports of countries from the Andean Community, Central America, Chile, and Mexico.
Keywords
Machinery trade Fragmentation International production networks Latin AmericaJEL Classification
F14 F15 F231 Introduction
In the past few decades international trade has increased exponentially and production fragmentation was one of the main causes. The fragmentation process, referred as “trade in tasks” by Grossman and Rossi-Hansberg (2008), has led to an increase in global integration, generating a web of economic interactions commonly denoted as international production networks. In the beginning, this change involved mostly trade among rich nations, but the real “revolution started when supply chain trade gained importance among high-tech and low-wage nations between 1985 and 1995” (Baldwin and Lopez-Gonzalez 2015). Production fragmentation opened new possibilities of economic growth to developing countries, allowing their engagement in the production process of manufactured goods that they were not able to produce.
The expansion of production networks changed the rules of the economic development game, facilitating developing countries’ access to networks, global markets, capital, knowledge, and technology (OECD 2013). Previously, a country had to climb every single step in the industrial development ladder, mastering all production processes, to manufacture a given good. However, the advent of production networks offered the possibility of skipping steps in the catch-up procedure through the acquisition of knowledge and technology from third countries and the specialization in one or few steps of the production process. Understanding these changes and their consequent implications is crucial to draw policies that integrate a country in this new production structure and allow it to explore the best possibilities for guaranteeing sustainable economic growth and development.
The empirical literature about production fragmentation is very rich, with many studies focusing on the regions where production fragmentation is more developed: East Asia, the European Union, and North America.1 Although the demand is growing for the analysis of the current situation and the effects that this new trend can have on Latin America, the literature is still incipient.
A few papers provide some information about the status of production fragmentation in Latin America based on descriptive analysis. Aminian et al. (2009) compared the economic integration process in East Asia and Latin America, analyzing the characteristics and intensity of intra-bloc and inter-bloc trade. They used a revealed comparative advantage (RCA) index to identify the share of traded manufacture parts and components with comparative advantage in the intra-bloc trade. Curran and Zignago (2013) studied the regionalization of trade in South America from 1994 to 2007, differentiating the trade flows by the end use of the products and the level of embodied technology. They concluded that the trade agreements have not extensively affected the regional trade level and that trade of intermediate products was still very low, indicating that regional production networks were still under-developed. Calfat et al. (2011) investigated the participation of Argentina, Brazil, Guatemala, and Nicaragua in fragmented world production. They concluded that Brazil was the only country with a consolidated participation in fragmented production. Fung et al. (2015a) used manufacturing trade data, classified according to the Standard International Trade Classification (SITC), to compare production sharing in Latin America, North America, and East Asia from 1985 to 2006. They identified the existence of a relatively thick production network involving the trade of parts of motor vehicles, telecommunication equipment, and electronic components. However, it was concentrated on Mexico’s trade with US and Canada, while Brazil also played a smaller role. Fung et al. (2015b) used the same data and methodology to compare Brazil, China, and Mexico’s participation in production networks. They analyzed the international trade patterns for the period 1990–2010, identifying that China’s global presence in the trade of parts and components increased. Although Mexico concentrated its trade of parts and components with the US, the data showed that China has become a major source of parts and components to Mexico and Brazil. The authors highlight the increasing importance of a Pan-Pacific link and a possible creation of a China–Brazil–Mexico production network.
Florensa et al. (2015) produced the first paper that used a quantitative framework to analyze economic integration and production fragmentation in Latin America. Using trade data classified according to the Broad Economic Categories (BEC), the authors analyzed the impact that changes in import of intermediate goods from different world regions had in the development of Latin America’s regional trade. They found evidence of increasing regional production networks and the importance of other regions as suppliers of intermediate products, with special attention on China.
Given the importance of this topic to the development literature and that production networks in Latin America are still understudied, this work contributes to the literature shedding light on the evolution of Latin American machinery industry. The first reason to focus on this industry is that machinery final products have a high level of complexity and use of a large number of parts and components, being the most developed manufacturing industry in terms of production fragmentation. Consequently, when the industry is more fragmented, a country will have more opportunities to engage in the production network. The second reason is that the high level of fragmentation and the availability of disaggregated trade data allow us to classify this industry into four different sectors. This division permits the development of a finer correspondence between parts and components and final products for a specific sector, reducing the bias that more aggregated data can generate. Finally, the share of machinery in Latin American exports and imports of manufactured products in 1996 was approximately 49.5 and 55.8%, respectively, while in 2011, the shares increased to 55.5 and 56.7%, respectively. Therefore, machinery is the most important industry in the region’s manufacturing trade.2
The contribution of this article is threefold. First, to the best of our knowledge, this is the first article to analyze the quality effects that the changes in the structural composition of suppliers of parts and components have had in the development of regional machinery production networks in Latin America. Second, different from the previous papers on Latin American production networks that use aggregated intermediate manufacture data, we focus our analysis on a specific industry and use disaggregated data. Third, in this paper we adopt a model similar to Florensa et al. (2015), but estimate it using the PPML method instead of the ordinary least squares (OLS) to control the zero trade values and the data heteroscedasticity.
The study is organized as follows. Section 2 includes a descriptive analysis of Latin America’s participation in the machinery trade. In Sect. 3, we present the data and in Sect. 4 we describe the empirical methodology employed. Section 5 shows the results of the quantity analysis, while Sect. 6 contains the results for the quality analysis. The final considerations of the paper are available in Sect. 7.
2 Machinery international trade and Latin America
In this section, we used trade data—classified according to the Harmonized System (HS) disaggregated to the six-digit level—to analyze the machinery international market and Latin America’s participation in it in 1996 and 2011. We also considered the changes in trade patterns from a trade margin and product sophistication perspective to identify modifications in Latin American countries’ trade basket composition.
2.1 Descriptive analysis: traded values
Total values of exports and imports per region in 1996 and 2011 (in million US$).
Source Chang and Kimura (2015)
The idiosyncrasies of Latin America, a heterogeneous region composed of countries of different sizes and governments with different political and economic orientation, localized in a vast territory full of geographical barriers, such as the Andes Mountains and the Amazon Forest, are possible reasons for its low level of engagement in production networks. Another reason, identified by Moreira et al. (2013), is the quality of the local infrastructure that penalizes the trade, increasing the freight costs or simply making it impracticable at competitive prices.
Latin America`s total value of machinery products trade in 1996 and 2011 (in million US$).
Source Author’s calculation, using data available from the UN Comtrade
Compound annual growth rate of machinery trade from 1996 to 2011
Parts and components (%) | Final products (%) | Total (%) | |
---|---|---|---|
East Asia | |||
Exports | 7.1 | 6.4 | 6.7 |
Imports | 6.6 | 4.6 | 5.7 |
EU | |||
Exports | 4.5 | 3.7 | 4.1 |
Imports | 4.2 | 3.6 | 3.9 |
NAFTA | |||
Exports | 1.2 | 2.3 | 1.8 |
Imports | 2.6 | 4.0 | 3.4 |
LA | |||
Exports | 10.1 | 7.9 | 9.0 |
Imports | 7.1 | 6.9 | 7.0 |
ROW | |||
Exports | 5.1 | 5.7 | 5.4 |
Imports | 6.9 | 7.9 | 7.6 |
Composition of suppliers of machinery parts and components in 1996 and 2011.
Source Author’s calculation, using data available from the UN Comtrade
From the perspective of production fragmentation logic, a country purchases more parts and components from a given region if these products have some comparative advantage. The existing literature highlights two channels through which access to inputs can benefit a country: an efficiency gain in the production process by the acquisition of cheaper and/or higher quality inputs (Amiti and Konings 2007; Goldberg et al. 2010) and the possibility of having access to inputs that previously could not be produced domestically or obtained from a third country (Goldberg et al. 2009). In both cases, a gain in productivity and changes in production pattern are expected. Based on this fact, we consider the hypothesis that the increase in import of parts and components, especially from East Asia, should be beneficial to Latin American machinery production networks.
In the next subsection, we analyze the trade margins to identify possible trade pattern modifications.
2.2 Descriptive analysis: the trade margins approach
The trade flow can be decomposed in extensive and intensive margins, revealing how the intensification of trade in existing relations and the beginning or ending of trade relations contribute to change this flow. Although the intensive margin is expected to be the main factor responsible for the changes, authors such as Hummels and Klenow (2005) and Kehoe and Ruhl (2013) identified that in situations of considerable trade growth the extensive margin contribution is also relevant. Our main interest in observing the extensive margins is to identify evidence of changes in Latin American countries’ import and export baskets.
A country’s trade relation is understood as a product–destination pair in the case of exports and a product–supplier pair in the case of imports. Given an initial and a final period, if a pair is active in both periods it is classified as a continuing pair. If country A imported (exported) a given product from (to) country B in the first period and then does not in the second period, but it still imports (exports) the product in question from (to) a third country, we have an exit of supplier (destination). If a similar situation occurs, but in the second period the product in question is not imported (exported) from (to) any other country, then it is classified as an exit of product. If in the second period, country A imports (exports) a product that was not imported (exported) from (to) any other country in the first period, then this new relation is classified as an enter of product. If in the second period, country A starts to import (export) from (to) country B a product that was already imported (exported) in the first period from (to) a third country, then this new relation is classified as an entry of supplier (destination).
Number of product–supplier pairs in machinery parts and components imports according to the trade margins from 1996 to 2011.
Source Author’s calculation, using data available from the UN Comtrade
Decomposition of growth in machinery parts and components imports according to the trade margins from 1996 to 2011 (%).
Source Author’s calculation, using data available from the UN Comtrade
Number of product–destination pairs in machinery exports according to the trade margins from 1996 to 2011.
Source Author’s calculation, using data available from the UN Comtrade
Decomposition of growth in machinery parts and components exports according to the trade margins from 1996 to 2011 (%).
Source Author’s calculation, using data available from the UN Comtrade
Number of machinery products traded by country according to their region. There are a total of 433 machinery parts and components and 691 machinery final products.
Source Author’s calculation, using data available from the UN Comtrade
Given the evidence of change in the import and export pattern of Latin American countries, in the next subsection we analyze the changes on traded products quality.
2.3 Descriptive analysis: sophistication level
Concomitant to the increase in Latin America’s machinery trade flow and changes in the structural composition of machinery parts and components suppliers, a modification in the trade basket composition is expected. To evaluate this change, we used the PRODY index5 developed in Hausmann et al. (2007). According to the authors, the PRODY “index is a weighted average of the per capita GDP of countries exporting a given product, and thus represents the income level associated with that product”. In other words, this index attributes to each one of the products a value that varies according to the share and per capita GDP of the countries that export it. This result means that products with higher PRODY values were exported more by developed countries, while products with lower PRODY values were exported more by developing countries. The PRODY index can be used as a proxy for the sophistication of the product.
Summary statistics of the PRODY index by products aggregation
Products aggregation | Mean | Median | SD | Min | Max | Observations |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
All goods | 14,171.7 | 14,076.5 | 6110.3 | 747.7 | 46,860.5 | 5023 |
Non-manufactured goods | 11,670.5 | 10,999.9 | 6191.0 | 747.7 | 32,835.9 | 1022 |
Manufactured goods | 13,896.5 | 13,446.5 | 6097.1 | 809.5 | 46,860.5 | 2877 |
Machinery goods | 17,150.3 | 17,289.3 | 4705.8 | 3730.2 | 35,433.8 | 1124 |
Average sophistication level of the machinery parts and components import basket.
Source Author’s calculation, using data available from the UN Comtrade
Average sophistication level of the machinery parts and components and final products export basket.
Source Author’s calculation, using data available from the UN Comtrade
2.4 Descriptive analysis: machinery sector data
Latin America machinery parts and components import composition by sector in 1996 and 2011.
Source Author’s calculation, using data available from the UN Comtrade
Latin America machinery export composition by sector in 1996 and 2011.
Source Author’s calculation, using data available from the UN Comtrade
In view of the facts presented in this section, the change in Latin America’s machinery trade pattern, the increase in trade flows and the modification in the average sophistication level of the traded products, in the next sections, we present the data and methodology employed to study the effects that changes in the structural composition of machinery parts and components suppliers had in the expansion of Latin American production networks and in the sophistication of the intra-bloc export basket.
3 Data
In the economics literature, many studies have been conducted on the fragmentation of production with different ways of defining the object of study. Some scholars employ a more comprehensive definition of production networks, including in their analysis all inputs used, from the raw materials to the final product. To capture all production steps they use international input–output tables.7 On the other hand, some scholars do not consider the raw materials in their analysis, understanding that just the trade of parts and components used in a given industry should be analyzed. This second group of researchers adopt a more refined classification to isolate parts and components from final products.8
We embrace the second view for two reasons: no international input–output data are available for the majority of the Latin American countries, and the second definition permits the use of more disaggregated and specific data. Considering that the machinery industry presents a high level of complexity and uses a large number of parts and components, we adopted this industry as our object of study.
The analysis of machinery production networks was based on the classification of the machinery trade in parts and components and final products.9 The data used was collected from the United Nations Commodity Trade Statistics Database (UN Comtrade), classified according to the HS disaggregated to the six-digit level. The machinery industry comprises all the goods categorized as general machinery sector (HS84), electric machinery sector (HS85), transport equipment sector (HS86–89), and precision machinery sector (HS90–92).
We consider the import of parts and components from countries that were responsible for at least 0.01% of the international machinery trade in 2011. The selected 89 countries are grouped in six regions.10 We define Latin America as the group of 17 countries consisting of Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Ecuador, El Salvador, Guatemala, Honduras, Mexico, Nicaragua, Panama, Paraguay, Peru, Uruguay, and Venezuela.
The PRODY measure was employed as the qualitative measure for the export and import basket of Latin American countries.11 We also used tariff data and the depth of the Preferential Trade Agreements (PTA)12 to account for the level of integration of the Latin American economies. The tariff data were collected from the World Integrated Trade Solution (WITS)13 and the PTAs depth measures were calculated based on Mulabdic et al. (2017) using the contents of trade agreements from the World Bank database (Hofmann et al. 2016). Given the availability of tariff and trade data, this study is restricted to the period from 1996 to 2011.
4 Methodology
Because the core of production networks is regionally concentrated, in this work, we focus on the impacts that changes in the structural composition of parts and components suppliers have on Latin America’s intra-bloc exports. For this empirical exercise, we use a model known as the workhorse of empirical international trade analysis: the gravity model (Baier and Bergstrand 2007). The gravity model is distinguished by its good fit and its parsimonious and tractable representation of economic interactions among many countries, also allowing for disaggregation of the trade in different levels of geographical organization and product classification (Anderson 2011).
To quantify the impact that changes in the structural composition of parts and components suppliers had on the development of the intra-bloc machinery trade, we follow the methodology proposed by Florensa et al. (2015), an augmented gravity model that accounts for the effect of the import of intermediate products. The adoption of such a framework is justified by the fact that, different from the standard gravity framework, this version accounts for the effect that the import of parts and components of a given sector from a given supplier have on the Latin American intra-bloc exports. The proposed model assumes that in the first period, Latin American countries can import parts and components from any region of the world. These parts and components are employed to produce other parts and components that in a second period will be used domestically or traded with another country. Alternatively, they can be used to manufacture a final product that will be consumed domestically or traded with a third country. We assume that Latin American production networks are created when Latin American countries use parts and components imported from any region of the world to produce a final product or other parts and components that are exported to another Latin American country.
The Latin American intra-bloc trade of final products and parts and components in a given year is explained by the tariffs imposed by the importer country in the same year and the exporter country imports of parts and components in the previous year. We augment the Florensa et al. (2015) model to capture the possible effects of the non-tariff barriers by adding a PTA depth measure. The PTA depth index calculation follows Mulabdic et al. (2017): based on the content of the trade agreements database, we count the number of legally enforceable provisions covered by each agreement and normalize it between 0 and 1.
One difference between this work and that of Florensa et al. (2015) is the definition of the object of study. As already mentioned, we selected a more specific object of study, focusing on the machinery industry alone. This allows us to use more disaggregated and detailed data, increasing the refinement of the parts and components and final products correspondence. Additionally, we can classify machinery industry products into four different sectors, decreasing the bias that can result from the use of aggregated data.
Based on previous works about production fragmentation and use of imported inputs, it is expected that the purchase of parts and components from another country should provide some efficiency gain or advantage to Latin American countries. Based on this fact, we expect that the increase in imports of parts and components from the East Asian region should guarantee a production gain for Latin American countries, increasing the intra-bloc machinery trade.
An important contribution of this paper is that the analysis is not limited to the quantity impact of the import of parts and components on the intra-bloc trade; we also propose a way of verifying quality changes. Since we know that there was a change in the shares of machinery parts and components providers, we attempt to evaluate if this variation also produced a modification in the Latin American intra-bloc trade pattern. Once again, it is expected that if the East Asian region is more efficient in the production of machinery parts and components, providing inputs with higher quality and/or cheaper prices, Latin American countries should be able to diversify and improve the quality of their intra-bloc trade basket.
5 Results: quantity analysis
A common characteristic of trade data is the existence of missing and zero trade values. As the natural logarithm of zero does not exist, the estimated regressions do not consider the zero trade values that are important information about the trade pattern. The dropped data are information not used in the estimation, possibly leading to a bias in the regression results.14 To avoid this problem, we estimate the regressions using the pseudo-Poisson maximum likelihood (PPML) method (Santos Silva and Tenreyro 2006). The PPML is the most accepted technique in the gravity model literature, allowing us to account for the observations with zero trade values.15 In addition, trade data are plagued by heteroscedasticity, consequently the use of OLS can lead to the estimation of biased elasticities (Santos Silva and Tenreyro 2006).
We first estimate Eqs. (2) and (3) for the values of the pooled machinery intra-bloc exports. We also consider separate estimations for the main machinery sectors: electric machinery and transport equipment.
The effect of imports of machinery parts and components on Latin American intra-bloc machinery exports
Final products | Parts and components | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Pooled machinery | Electric machinery | Transport equipment | Pooled machinery | Electric machinery | Transport equipment | |
Tariff | − 0.17*** (0.05) | − 0.12** (0.06) | − 0.05 (0.08) | − 0.03 (0.04) | − 0.03 (0.04) | − 0.05 (0.04) |
Lagged imports of parts and components from ROW | 0.15*** (0.05) | − 0.24** (0.09) | 0.18** (0.07) | 0.19*** (0.05) | 0.08 (0.07) | 0.04 (0.06) |
Lagged imports of parts and components from EU | − 0.03 (0.08) | 0.18 (0.23) | − 0.03 (0.21) | − 0.20 (0.13) | − 0.42*** (0.12) | − 0.08 (0.12) |
Lagged imports of parts and components from EA | 0.45*** (0.06) | 0.00 (0.15) | 0.15 (0.19) | 0.05 (0.07) | 0.38*** (0.10) | 0.31 (0.20) |
Lagged imports of parts and components from LA | 0.53*** (0.08) | 0.07 (0.09) | − 0.12 (0.18) | 0.64*** (0.08) | 0.16 (0.11) | 0.39*** (0.14) |
Lagged imports of parts and components from US and Canada | − 0.32*** (0.08) | − 0.52*** (0.15) | − 0.32 (0.23) | 0.31*** (0.08) | − 0.17* (0.09) | − 0.49*** (0.18) |
Lagged imports of parts and components from China and HK | − 0.27*** (0.05) | 0.22** (0.09) | 0.06 (0.10) | − 0.02 (0.06) | 0.02 (0.10) | 0.02 (0.07) |
PTA depth | − 0.24 (0.26) | − 0.66*** (0.22) | − 0.20 (0.65) | − 0.33 (0.29) | − 0.09 (0.20) | 0.03 (0.49) |
Observations | 16,943 | 4320 | 4032 | 16,667 | 4256 | 3794 |
R 2 | 0.87 | 0.90 | 0.94 | 0.87 | 0.94 | 0.97 |
Results in the second column refer to the electric machinery trade. The import tariff coefficient is negative, indicating that a decrease of 1% in the tariffs imposed on electric machinery parts and components imports, all ceteris paribus, stimulates an increase of 0.12% in intra-bloc exports of electric machinery final products. Once again, the coefficient for imports from North America is negative, indicating that a 1% increase in imports from this region causes a decrease in the intra-bloc exports of final electric machinery of 0.52%. Imports from the ROW also have a negative impact of 0.24%. On the opposite side, a 1% increase in imports of electric machinery parts and components from China promotes an intensification of 0.22% in the intra-bloc trade of final products. The PTA depth coefficient is statistically significant and indicates that deeper agreements lead to a decrease in the intra-regional trade of electric machinery final products. According to Hofmann et al. (2016), agreements between developing countries are in general less deep and focus more on the decrease of import tariffs, since they are still high.17 This is in accordance with our findings that show that decreases in import tariffs are more efficient than deeper agreements in the promotion of intra-bloc electric machinery final products exports. Additionally, in Latin America shallow agreements embrace more members, while deeper ones are in general bilateral agreements involving Mexico and Central American countries. Consequently, members of shallower agreements, such as the Mercosur, promote higher trade flows among themselves than members of deeper agreements. Lastly, according to Baier and Bergstrand (2007), all PTAs are “phased-in” over time, approximately 5–10 years. Therefore, older and shallower agreements, implemented in the 1990s, should have bigger impacts than the deeper ones, the majority of which were implemented in 2009, only 2 years before the end of the period studied.18
With regard to transport equipment, the results are almost all statistically insignificant. The exception is the coefficient for imports from the ROW, indicating that a 1% increase in imports of transport equipment parts and components from this region leads to an increase of 0.18% in intra-bloc exports of final transport equipment.
The second half of Table 3 displays the intra-bloc parts and components export coefficients. In this case, import tariff and PTA depth coefficients are statistically insignificant, signaling an increase in regional integration through the decrease of the import tariffs or non-tariff barriers would not affect the production fragmentation and relocation inside Latin America. Imports of parts and components from LA, North America, and the ROW have positive and statistically significant coefficients. As observed in Florensa et al. (2015), imports of parts and components from these regions generate what they called a “complementary effect”. In other words, they stimulate production fragmentation and its relocation inside Latin America, since parts and components imported by a Latin American country in the first period produce other parts and components that will be used in a third Latin American country, promoting these countries engagement in machinery productions networks. A 1% increase in parts and components imports from LA results in an increase of 0.64% of the intra-bloc export of parts and components. Imports from North America promote an increase of 0.31%, while imports from the ROW have a smaller effect of 0.19%.
In the specific case of electric machinery, imports from EA stimulate the intra-bloc trade of parts and components with a coefficient of 0.39%, while imports from European Union (EU) and North America have a negative effect. In the case of transport equipment, the LA coefficient is positive, while the North American one is negative. Florensa et al. (2015) refer to the situation when coefficients are negative as the “substitution effect”, because instead of enhancing the development of production networks among Latin American countries, it promotes trade inside domestic markets or with countries in third regions.
Evidence indicates that increases in the import of parts and components from LA have the biggest positive impact in the creation of a Latin American machinery production network. This result aligns with Florensa et al. (2015) and the production fragmentation theory that states that the core of production networks is regionally organized. Imports from North America, a region that is geographically close to Latin America and known for engaging in back-and-forth intra-firm production network transactions with Mexico and Central American countries, presented mixed results. It stimulates the intra-bloc trade of machinery parts and components in general, but decreases the trade of final products. Conversely, the results indicate that in the specific case of electric machineries, imports from EA and China foment production fragmentation. This result also aligns with Florensa et al. (2015) and Fung et al. (2015b) who verified an increase of parts and components supplies from Asian countries supporting Latin America’s engagement in production networks.
As mentioned in Sect. 2, Latin America is an area where economic integration still lags behind other regions of the globe. Although there are 21 different PTAs signed by LA countries, none of them integrates the whole region. Given this fact, we perform one extra exercise to explore the heterogeneity inside the region. Based on economic proximity and negotiated PTAs, we classified Latin America into three subregions: one composed of Argentina, Brazil, Paraguay, and Uruguay, who are members of Mercosur; a second composed of Bolivia, Colombia, Ecuador, Peru, and Venezuela who are members of the Andean Community (CAN); and a third with the members of Central America (Costa Rica, El Salvador, Guatemala, Honduras, Nicaragua, and Panama), Mexico and Chile.19
The effect of imports of machinery parts and components on Latin American intra-bloc machinery exports by subregion
Final products | Parts and components | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
CE, Mexico and Chile | Andean Community | Mercosur | CE, Mexico and Chile | Andean Community | Mercosur | |
Tariff | − 0.28*** (0.07) | 0.06 (0.09) | − 0.23*** (0.07) | 0.05 (0.08) | − 0.05 (0.10) | − 0.10*** (0.03) |
Lagged imports of parts and components from ROW | 0.04 (0.06) | − 0.13 (0.09) | 0.15** (0.07) | 0.23*** (0.06) | − 0.14 (0.12) | 0.10** (0.05) |
Lagged imports of parts and components from EU | − 0.18 (0.13) | − 0.18 (0.25) | 0.12 (0.19) | − 0.45*** (0.12) | − 0.17 (0.20) | − 0.17 (0.13) |
Lagged imports of parts and components from EA | 0.15*** (0.06) | 0.36** (0.17) | 0.66*** (0.13) | 0.25*** (0.08) | − 0.04 (0.19) | 0.03 (0.09) |
Lagged imports of parts and components from LA | 0.32*** (0.09) | 0.49*** (0.13) | 0.10 (0.11) | 0.45*** (0.07) | 0.16 (0.12) | 0.05 (0.09) |
Lagged imports of parts and components from US and Canada | 0.42*** (0.10) | − 0.02 (0.25) | − 0.92*** (0.15) | 0.58*** (0.10) | 0.40* (0.21) | − 0.25*** (0.09) |
Lagged imports of parts and components from China and HK | − 0.22*** (0.05) | − 0.38*** (0.13) | − 0.12 (0.09) | 0.06 (0.07) | 0.13 (0.11) | 0.26*** (0.05) |
PTA depth | − 0.60*** (0.22) | 0.48 (0.56) | 0.66 (1.02) | − 1.29*** (0.35) | − 0.06 (0.31) | 1.03 (0.85) |
Observations | 0.71 | 0.69 | 0.91 | 0.90 | 0.73 | 0.92 |
R 2 | 7807 | 5104 | 4032 | 7635 | 5104 | 3928 |
We conclude that, different from Central American, Mexico and Chile, production networks promoted by Mercosur countries depend more on imports from China and EA, while imports from North America have a negative impact. In this case, it seems that geographical and economic proximity still play an important role, with North American imports fomenting the first regions’ engagement in production fragmentation, while in Mercosur’s case, a region more distant from North America, the imports from EA and China are more important.
6 Results: quality analysis
Considering the wide range of machinery products and that some are more sophisticated than the others, our next step is to examine which regions provide parts and components that promote Latin American production networks of products more similar to the ones produced by developed countries. Being involved in the manufacturing process of products with higher sophistication level instead of just buying the final product from other regions, Latin American countries gain access to technology, benefit from positive spillover effects, and increase the possibilities of enjoying economic growth.
The effect of import composition of machinery parts and components on Latin American intra-bloc machinery exports sophistication
Final products | Parts and components | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Pooled machinery | Electric machinery | Transport equipment | Pooled machinery | Electric machinery | Transport equipment | |
Tariff | 0.05*** (0.01) | 0.07*** (0.01) | 0.05*** (0.02) | 0.08*** (0.01) | 0.08*** (0.01) | 0.06*** (0.02) |
Lagged imports of parts and components from ROW | 0.01** (0.01) | 0.02 (0.01) | 0.00 (0.01) | 0.04*** (0.01) | 0.01 (0.01) | 0.01 (0.01) |
Lagged imports of parts and components from EU | 0.04*** (0.01) | 0.04* (0.02) | 0.03 (0.05) | 0.04*** (0.01) | − 0.03 (0.02) | − 0.01 (0.05) |
Lagged imports of parts and components from EA | 0.02*** (0.01) | 0.03 (0.03) | 0.01 (0.04) | 0.04*** (0.01) | − 0.04* (0.02) | − 0.03 (0.03) |
Lagged imports of parts and components from LA | 0.02*** (0.01) | 0.06** (0.03) | − 0.03 (0.06) | 0.02** (0.01) | 0.03 (0.03) | 0.00 (0.05) |
Lagged imports of parts and components from US and Canada | 0.06*** (0.01) | 0.07*** (0.03) | − 0.02 (0.04) | 0.10*** (0.01) | − 0.01 (0.03) | 0.01 (0.04) |
Lagged imports of parts and components from China and HK | 0.00 (0.01) | 0.03 (0.02) | 0.02 (0.01) | 0.01 (0.01) | 0.04*** (0.02) | 0.00 (0.01) |
PTA depth | 0.01 (0.03) | 0.03 (0.05) | 0.04 (0.07) | 0.01 (0.04) | − 0.08* (0.05) | 0.07 (0.06) |
Observations | 16,943 | 4320 | 4032 | 16,667 | 4256 | 3794 |
R 2 | 0.42 | 0.46 | 0.49 | 0.44 | 0.51 | 0.55 |
Considering parts and components suppliers, we verify that imports from the ROW, EU, EA, LA, and North America promoted an increase in the sophistication of the final products traded inside Latin America. A 1% increase in North American participation in the import basket composition, all ceteris paribus, promotes an increase of 0.06% in the quality of the intra-bloc export basket, while imports from EU promoted an increase of 0.04%, followed by increases of 0.02% in the case of imports from LA or EA, and 0.01% for the ROW. The second column reveals that imports just from LA and North America had a positive effect in the electric machinery sector, while the coefficients for imports from other regions are statistically insignificant. Increases of 1% in imports from North America promote an increase of 0.07% in the quality of final electric machinery intra-bloc export basket, while imports from LA promote an increase of 0.06%. Transport equipment coefficients were all statistically insignificant. In the second half of Table 5, we verify similar results for the case of pooled machinery data. North American imports promote an increase of 0.1% in the quality of the parts and components export basket, while imports from the EU and EA promote an increase of 0.04% each. In column 5, the coefficients are slightly different, revealing that imports only from China promote a 0.04% increase in the intra-bloc export basket of electric machinery parts and components, while imports from EA have a negative effect. Once again, transport equipment coefficients are statistically insignificant.
Machinery imported parts and components PRODY index mean
Latin America | CE, Mexico and Chile | Andean Community | Mercosur | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
1996 | 2011 | 1996 | 2011 | 1996 | 2011 | 1996 | 2011 | |
ROW | 18,273.1 | 18,358.7 | 17,997.5 | 18,005.2 | 18,569.9 | 18,808.3 | 18,453.3 | 18,503.4 |
EU | 17,492.8 | 17,652.7 | 17,418.5 | 17,327.4 | 17,581.6 | 18,067.0 | 17,530.3 | 17,785.3 |
North America | 16,870.1 | 17,576.7 | 16,735.8 | 17,245.1 | 17,032.2 | 17,577.7 | 16,935.9 | 18,238.5 |
EA | 16,629.9 | 17,106.3 | 16,535.6 | 16,930.5 | 16,742.7 | 17,258.1 | 16,677.4 | 17,268.1 |
LA | 16,389.4 | 16,313.9 | 16,256.1 | 15,845.9 | 16,188.2 | 16,486.5 | 16,907.2 | 17,034.1 |
China | 15,109.2 | 16,445.3 | 15,589.5 | 16,272.3 | 15,006.5 | 16,549.7 | 14,276.8 | 16,660.5 |
The effect of import composition of machinery parts and components on Latin American intra-bloc machinery exports sophistication by subregion
Final products | Parts and components | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
CE, Mexico and Chile | Andean Community | Mercosur | CE, Mexico and Chile | Andean Community | Mercosur | |
Tariff | 0.04*** (0.01) | 0.01 (0.02) | − 0.24*** (0.07) | 0.11*** (0.01) | 0.04** (0.02) | 0.02 (0.01) |
Lagged imports of parts and components from ROW | 0.02*** (0.01) | − 0.01 (0.01) | 0.14** (0.06) | 0.04*** (0.01) | 0.03*** (0.01) | 0.07*** (0.01) |
Lagged imports of parts and components from EU | 0.04*** (0.02) | − 0.08** (0.04) | − 0.25 (0.19) | 0.05*** (0.02) | − 0.10*** (0.04) | − 0.01 (0.04) |
Lagged imports of parts and components from EA | 0.02* (0.01) | 0.04* (0.02) | 0.39*** (0.14) | 0.04*** (0.01) | − 0.07*** (0.03) | 0.06*** (0.02) |
Lagged imports of parts and components from LA | 0.01 (0.01) | − 0.02 (0.03) | − 0.13 (0.12) | − 0.02** (0.01) | − 0.02 (0.03) | 0.01 (0.02) |
Lagged imports of parts and components from US and Canada | − 0.04* (0.02) | 0.13** (0.06) | − 0.77*** (0.14) | − 0.05* (0.03) | − 0.09 (0.05) | − 0.08*** (0.03) |
Lagged imports of parts and components from China and HK | − 0.04*** (0.01) | − 0.02 (0.02) | − 0.12 (0.08) | − 0.04*** (0.01) | − 0.08*** (0.02) | − 0.03* (0.02) |
PTA depth | 0.06 (0.04) | − 0.14** (0.06) | 0.56 (1.01) | 0.15*** (0.05) | − 0.06 (0.08) | − 0.24* (0.14) |
Observations | 0.46 | 0.34 | 0.91 | 0.47 | 0.37 | 0.51 |
R 2 | 7807 | 5104 | 4032 | 7635 | 5104 | 3928 |
For the Andean Community members, imports of parts and components from EU have a negative impact, while imports from EA and North America increase the sophistication of the machinery final products they export inside Latin America. When intra-bloc exports of parts and components are considered, imports from the ROW assume a positive coefficient. Although Table 6 revealed no decrease in the PRODY mean from 1996 to 2011, after econometrically controlling all variables, the model reveals a negative effect on intra-bloc exports of parts and components in the cases of imports from China, EA and EU.
Increases in EA and the ROW participation in Mercosur’s import basket composition have a positive impact on Mercosur members’ exports of machinery final products and parts and components, while North American participation in the import basket have a negative impact.
These results indicated that depending on the subregion, the origin of the imports can have a positive or negative effect on the sophistication level of the machinery exports inside Latin America. In general, imports from EA and the ROW had positive effects, while imports from North America and China had negative impacts. However, when we consider all Latin American countries, we verify positive contributions from North American imports. The results indicate that in the case of imports from China, the effect on the intra-bloc exports sophistication level were not positive as expected, revealing that its exports to Latin America were still composed of cheaper and less sophisticated parts and components. The exception is in the specific case of electric machinery, where imports from China increased the sophistication of the intra-bloc exports of parts and components.
7 Final considerations
In this paper, we investigated how the changes in the structural composition of Latin America’s suppliers of machinery parts and components affected the development of Latin American regional production networks. In our analysis, we considered a quantity and a quality dimension of the impact of these imports.
In the first part of the paper, the descriptive analysis indicated a growth in the import of parts and components from all regions of the world. However, we observed that the growth in imports from the East Asian region was higher, resulting in a change in the structural composition of the suppliers. Concomitant with this composition change, we also verified a modification in the sophistication level on the intra-bloc exports. In the second part of the paper, we proceeded with an econometric analysis to identify from which regions the import of parts and components contributed more to develop production networks inside Latin America and increase the sophistication level of the traded products. The quantity analysis provided evidence that Latin American production networks increased during the studied period, and they were fomented by import of machinery parts and components from the ROW, LA, EA, and North America. Imports of parts and components from LA had the biggest positive impact in the creation of a Latin American machinery production network, while imports from North America stimulated the intra-bloc trade of machinery parts and components in general, decreasing the trade in specific machinery sectors. The expected result that the increase in imports from EA and China fomented production networks inside Latin America was confirmed for the specific case of electric machineries. Conversely, imports of parts and components from North America did not stimulate the intra-bloc trade of machineries final products and parts and components for the two specific sectors analyzed.
Exploring subregional heterogeneities, we identified that imports from North America had the highest positive impact in intra-bloc exports in the cases of the exports from Central America, Chile and Mexico subregions, as well as the Andean Community. Imports from EA and China had the highest positive effects in the case of exports from Mercosur countries. It is possible that geographical and economic proximity played an important role in this result, with North American imports fomenting the first two regions’ engagement in production fragmentation, while imports from EA and China were more important for Mercosur members.
Considering the second dimension studied, the sophistication of the products traded in Latin America’s regional production networks, the results provided evidence that partially supported the hypothesis that increases in imports of parts and components from Asian countries promote an increase in the quality of the intra-bloc export basket. The EA coefficient was positive for the pooled machinery data in Latin America and almost all subregions, while imports from China increased the sophistication of intra-bloc exports of electric machinery parts and components. The coefficients for subregional pooled machinery data imports from China were negative, revealing that its exports to Latin America were still composed of cheaper and less sophisticated parts and components. The results from imports from North America were mixed, with negative coefficients in the subregional cases and positive coefficients when all Latin American countries were analyzed.
The findings of this paper indicate that Latin American governments should consider the possibility of being more proactive in the development of regional policies to facilitate the import and use of machinery parts and components. The heterogeneity between subregions indicates that countries from Mercosur could benefit more from imports from the EA and China to foment the expansion of regional production networks and the increase in the sophistication level of the machinery products traded inside Latin America, while North America appears as a natural and better option for the other countries. Moreover, Latin American countries could take advantage of the internalization of some machinery production steps to engage in machinery production networks and decrease the imports of machinery final products from third regions. These initial policies can proportionate economic growth and other positive spillover effects. In the medium and long term, these strategies could help Latin American countries overcome the lack of competitiveness in given machinery products and enhance the region’s participation in the international machinery trade.
Footnotes
- 1.
- 2.
The shares were calculated based on the harmonized system (HS) classification. The manufactured goods range from HS 28 to HS 92, while machinery products range from HS 84 to HS 92.
- 3.
The figures and table in this subsection present a conservative estimate of the situation in Latin America, given that Mexico trade data are accounted for in the NAFTA region. From the next subsection on, Mexico’s data will be considered as part of Latin America.
- 4.
Given the economic growth of China after the WTO accession in 2001, we consider the importance of disentangling the impacts of this country from the rest of the East Asian region. We separate the East Asian region into two groups: a first group composed only of China and Hong Kong (hereafter referred to as China), and a second group composed of the other countries in the region that we address as East Asia (EA). As mentioned before, after this subsection we consider Mexico as a member of Latin America.
- 5.
More specifically, the PRODY index of a product k is defined as \({\text{PROD}}\,Y_{k} = \mathop \sum \nolimits_{j} \frac{{(x_{jk} /X_{j} )}}{{\mathop \sum \nolimits_{j} (x_{jk} /X_{j} )}}Y_{j.}\), where \(x_{jk} /X_{j}\) is the value-share of the commodity k in the country j’s overall export basket; \(\sum\nolimits_{j} {(x_{jk} /X_{j} )}\) is the aggregated value-shares across all countries exporting good k.
- 6.
Non-manufactured goods are the products classified from HS 1 to HS 27 and HS 93 to HS 99; manufactured goods are the products from HS 28 to HS 83, and machinery includes the products from HS 84 to HS 92.
- 7.
- 8.
- 9.
This process was performed in accordance with the classification presented in Ando and Kimura (2005).
- 10.
The list containing the 89 countries divided by regions is available in the Table 8 in “Appendix”.
- 11.
We use the PRODY measures calculated by Hausmann et al. (2007). According to the authors they “constructed the PRODY measure for a consistent sample of countries that reported trade data in each of the years 1999–2001. These indexes are the result of an average of 3 years” (Hausmann et al. 2007). Because the chosen years are previous to the Chinese accession to the World Trade Organization, the possibility of a downward bias in the ranking of the machinery goods (in particular, final goods, given the increase in multinationals assembling their final products China) is minimized.
- 12.
We thank an anonymous referee for suggesting the use of PTAs depth to implicitly control non-tariff barriers.
- 13.
Tariff data were classified to HS six-digit level and when necessary was converted to the HS1992 version following the classification in Kimura and Obashi (2010).
- 14.
The share of dropped values when the OLS method is employed ranges from around 17–29% of the total values estimated with the PPML technique.
- 15.
In our database, we also have missing tariff and trade data for a given group of countries and products that affect the independent variables. Unfortunately, the PPML model cannot address this problem.
- 16.
The term North America refers to US and Canada.
- 17.
The mean of the import tariff between Latin American countries in the studied period was 6.89% for machinery final products and 5.64% for machinery parts and components. For the case of electric machinery, the average import tariffs are 9.92% for final products and 6.62% for parts and components.
- 18.
Table 9 in the “Appendix” contains the list of PTAs in force during the studied period.
- 19.
Venezuela was classified as part of CAN, because during the majority of the studied period it was a member of it. Chile and Mexico were aggregated with Central American economies given the existence of many PTAs among them and because both countries are not members of either Mercosur or CAN.
- 20.
Once the regions were selected based on PTAs, the PTA depth was dropped from the regressions.
Notes
Acknowledgements
I deeply appreciate the valuable comments from professors Fukunari Kimura, Kozo Kiyota, Toshihiro Okubo, Colin McKenzie, Masao Ogaki, and Yoshimasa Shirai from Keio University. I am thankful for the support from Professor Laura Márquez-Ramos and Juan Nelson Martínez Dahbura. I gratefully acknowledge the Keio University Doctorate Student Grant-in-Aid Program, the MEXT-supported Program for the Strategic Research Foundation at Private Universities, and Keio Economic Society for the financial support in part for this study. The analysis and results presented in this research are only the responsibility of the author.
References
- Aminian N, Fung KC, Ng F (2009) A comparative analysis of trade and economic integration in East Asia and Latin America. Econ Change Restruct 42:105–137CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Amiti M, Konings J (2007) Trade liberalization, intermediate inputs and productivity. Am Econ Rev 97:1611–1638CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Anderson JE (2011) The gravity model. Ann Rev Econ 3:133–160CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Anderson JE, van Wincoop E (2003) Gravity with gravitas: a solution to the border puzzle. Am Econ Rev 93(1):170–192CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Anderson JE, van Wincoop E (2004) Trade Costs. J Econ Lit 42(3):691–751CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Ando M, Kimura F (2005) The formation of international production and distribution networks in East Asia. In: Ito T, Rose AK (eds) International trade in East Asia. University of Chicago Press, ChicagoGoogle Scholar
- Ando M, Kimura F (2013a) Evolution of machinery production networks: linkage of North America with East Asia. ERIA Discussion Paper Series DP-2013-32, Economics Research Institute for ASEAN and East Asia (ERIA)Google Scholar
- Ando M, Kimura F (2013b) Production linkage of Asia and Europe via Central and Eastern Europe. J Econ Integr 28:204–240CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Athukorala P (2005) Product fragmentation and trade patterns in East Asia. Asian Econ Papers 4(3):1–27CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Athukorala P, Yamashita N (2006) Product fragmentation and trade integration: East Asia in a global context. N Am J Econ Finance 17(3):233–256CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Baier SL, Bergstrand JH (2007) Do Free Trade Agreements Actually Increase Members' International Trade? J Intern Econ 71(1):72–95CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Baldwin R, Lopez-Gonzalez J (2015) Supply-chain trade: a portrait of global patterns and several testable hypothesis. World Econ 38(11):1682–1721CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Calfat G, Cassimon D, Flôres RG Jr, Rivas A (2011) Far from champions, close to midgets—international production sharing in Central and South America. Rev de Econ y Estad 49:101–137Google Scholar
- Curran L, Zignago S (2013) Regional integration of trade in South America: how far has it progressed and in which sectors? Int Trade J 27(1):3–35CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Florensa LM, Márquez-Ramos L, Martínez-Zarzoso I, Recalde ML (2015) Regional versus global production networks: where does Latin America stand? Appl Econ 47(37):3938–3956CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Fung KC, Garcia-Herrero A, Siu A (2015a) Production sharing in Latin America and East Asia. Working Papers 0901, BBVA Bank, Economic Research DepartmentGoogle Scholar
- Fung KC, Hwang HC, Ng F, Seade J (2015b) Production networks and international trade: China, Brazil, and Mexico. N Am J Econ Finance 34:421–429CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Goldberg P, Khandelwal A, Pavcnik N, Topalova P (2009) Trade liberalization and new imported inputs. Am Econ Rev Papers Proc 99(2):494–500CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Goldberg P, Khandelwal A, Pavcnik N, Topalova P (2010) Trade imported intermediate inputs and domestic product growth: evidence from India. Q J Econ 125(4):1727–1767CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Grossman GM, Rossi-Hansberg E (2008) Trading tasks: a simple theory of offshoring. Am Econ Rev 98(5):1978–1997CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Harrigan J, Venables AJ (2004) Timeliness, trade and agglomeration. CEPR Discussion Paper, No, p 4294CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Hausmann R, Hwang J, Rodrik D (2007) What you export matters. J Econ Growth 12(1):1–15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Hofmann C, Osnago A, Ruta M (2016) Horizontal depth: a new database on the content of deep agreements. Mimeo, The World BankGoogle Scholar
- Hummels D, Klenow PJ (2005) The variety and quality of a nation`s exports. Am Econ Rev 95(3):704–723CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Jones R, Kierzkowski H (2005) International fragmentation and the new economic geography. N Am J Econ Finance 16:1–10CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Kehoe TJ, Ruhl KJ (2013) How important is the new goods margin in international trade? J Political Econ 121(2):358–392CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Kimura F, Obashi A (2010) International production networks in machinery industries: structure and its evolution. Working Papers DP-2010- 09, Economics Research Institute for ASEAN and East Asia (ERIA)Google Scholar
- Kimura F, Takahashi Y, Hayakawa K (2007) Fragmentation and parts and components trade: comparison between East Asia and Europe. N Am J Econ Finance 18(1):23–40CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Moreira MM, Blyde JS, Martincus CV, Molina D (2013) Too far to export: domestic transport costs and regional export disparities in Latin America and the Caribbean. IDB, Washington, DCGoogle Scholar
- Mulabdic A, Osnago A, Ruta M (2017) Deep integration and UK-EU trade relations. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 7947Google Scholar
- Ng F, Yeats A (2003) Major Trade Trends in East Asia : What are their Implications for Regional Cooperation and Growth? World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 3084. https://doi.org/10.1596/1813-9450-3084
- Obashi A, Kimura F (2016) Deepening and Widening of Production Networks in ASEAN. ERIA Discussion Paper Series DP-2016-09, Economics Research Institute for ASEAN and East Asia (ERIA)Google Scholar
- Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) (2013) Interconnected economies: benefiting from global value chains. OECD Publishing, ParisGoogle Scholar
- Santos Silva JMC, Tenreyro S (2006) The Log of Gravity. Rev Econ Stat 88(4):641–658CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Timmer M, Dietzenbacher E, Los B, Stehrer R, de Vries G (2015) An illustrated user guide to the world input-output database: the case of global automotive production. Rev Int Econ 23(3):575–605CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Yamashita N, Kohpaiboon A (2011). Trade in Supply Chains between ASEAN and China: Development and Implications. In: Findlay C (ed) ASEAN+1 FTAs and Global Value Chains in East Asia. ERIA Research Project Report 2010-29. ERIA, Jakarta, pp 25–51Google Scholar
- Yokota K (2008) Parts and Components trade and Production Networks in East Asia - A Panel Gravity Approach. In: Hiratsuka D, Uchida Y (eds) Vertical Specialization and Economic Integration in East Asia. Institute of Developing Economies JETROGoogle Scholar
Copyright information
Open AccessThis article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.