The villages of Barbote and Pyang are located in the far west region of Nepal, in neighboring districts. Both villages are heavily dependent on rice cultivation, similarly sized (around 1800 households), and equally distant to a major road (4 km). Despite similarities between the villages, citizens within them receive remarkably different levels of public services. Citizens in Barbote, who depend on rice cultivation for their livelihoods, are confident that they can find a crop extension agent if they need one, and a third of them have within the past year. Anuj,Footnote 1 the official in charge of agricultural extension services for Barbote’s district, provides these services with shockingly few resources: a staff of only 5 crop extension agents to serve over 82,000 farmers. However, what Anuj lacks in resources, he makes up for by embedding himself in the community. Having lived in the district for 24 years, he understands local agricultural conditions and leaves the district capital for field visits at least every other week.

Pyang differs notably from Barbote in both the resources deployed to provide public services and in the levels of services provided. Bishal, the official in charge of agricultural extension services for Pyang’s district, has 26 crop extension agents to serve 187,000 farmers (though this is far too few staff to effectively serve the population, it is nonetheless more than twice the ratio as Barbote). Despite this advantage, Bishal knows little about the community he serves, having lived there for less than 2 years and not recalling his last field visit outside the district capital. When asked the best way to expand agricultural production in his district, Bishal could not name a single policy area. Though citizens in Pyang are equally dependent on rice cultivation for their livelihoods, all surveyed citizens reported that no crop extension agents serve their village.

This example, based on two real (but anonymized) villages, highlights a broader puzzle. Despite shared socio-economic characteristics and geographic proximity, rural villages are not uniformly underserved by public services. Using a combination of elite interviews and nationally representative survey data from Nepal, we explore when and how state capacity plays a role in variations in the delivery of public services.

On the surface, the answer to this question is straightforward: higher capacity results in better service delivery. Yet, state capacity is a multi-faceted concept, potentially encompassing bureaucratic quality and professionalization, monopoly on the use of force within its borders, absence of corruption, autonomy from political interference, high levels of fiscal and military resources, and, among others, the ability to extract fiscal resources.Footnote 2 In other words, state capacity is equivalent to a “family resemblance concept” (Goertz 2006) with many constitutive elements. While these elements are often mutually reinforcing, they do not always flow together. For instance, a country like Rwanda is relatively poor but the state exerts high control over population and territory (Giraudy 2012). Whether one or more of these specific elements of capacity is more relevant for service delivery remains unclear but extremely policy-relevant. This is particularly true in developing countries where both donors and national governments devote scarce resources to improving capacity and need to prioritize interventions.

In this paper, we take into account various dimensions of state capacity and their geographic variation by focusing on Nepal, which is widely considered a uniformly “weak” state. Despite this characterization of low state capacity, we find that even in equally remote areas, access to services differs substantially. However, geographic variation in service delivery could be explained by policy choice as well as by the state’s ability to implement those policies. In order to isolate the role of capacity, we focus on a policy domain for which the public policy decision is made at the central level, but the responsibility to implement is delegated to the local level: agricultural extension. Indeed, the national level policy—“One extension agent, One Village”—reflects the intention of the central government to provide the public good uniformly across the country. Agricultural extension, which involves trained professionals sharing information on higher-yielding varieties of seeds and fertilizers, improved cultivation techniques, natural resource management, and market access opportunities (see Swanson and Davis 2014), plays a critical role in enhancing agricultural productivity growth (Fan and Zhang 2008). Agricultural productivity is central to rural livelihoods, and rural citizens in Nepal rank extension as one of the most important areas for public investment, ahead of health, education, and electricity access.Footnote 3

Our empirical strategy relies on three original data sources. One is a nationally representative survey of over 1000 rural households in 48 of the country’s 75 districts. The second is a series of structured, qualitative interviews with 50 District Agricultural Development Officers (DADOs), who are the bureaucrats in charge of agricultural extension in a district. The third is a set of semi-structured interviews with high-level agricultural policymakers in Nepal.Footnote 4 Drawing on this data, we capture six different dimensions of local, sectoral capacity. We find that traditional indicators of state capacity—human resources, staff professionalization, and bureaucratic autonomy—matter surprisingly little in shaping access to public services. Instead, local knowledge and intrinsic motivation of individual bureaucrats play a far greater role in shaping service access.

Any study of political geography faces identification challenges, confounded by factors which vary by district and also shape service delivery. We lend confidence to our findings by testing two alternative explanations for spatial variation in agricultural extension services—a village’s agricultural development potential and remoteness to agricultural service centers. We also probe the findings by conducting a placebo test, testing for the effects of current capacity on past levels of service delivery; we find no placebo effects.

The contributions of this paper are at least twofold. First, our unique data sources allow us to explore multiple dimensions of state capacity at the subnational level within a specific sector, which is rare for developing countries. Moreover, we do so in rural areas; whereas private sector providers may substitute for poor public services in urban areas, this is typically not an option in rural areas, making understanding state capacity in these contexts even more pressing. We show that all good things do not go together—different dimensions of state capacity do not necessarily correlate with each other—suggesting difficult trade-offs for policymakers about what to prioritize.

Secondly, the paper highlights the important role of individual bureaucrats in delivering public services in weak states. Where bureaucracies are not yet professionalized, lack resources, and are highly politicized, individual leadership plays an outsized role in whether citizens receive services. Bureaucrats who are able to embed themselves in local communities and to maintain motivation for serving them make more of a difference in improving service access for local communities than going from being the least- to the most-resourced district in the country. Of course, this is not to say that more resources, more autonomy, and more professionalization are not needed in Nepal, or in other weak states. Yet, given a context where even the district with the most staff to deploy toward public service delivery is still woefully under-resourced overall, the abilities and motivations of individual bureaucrats carry the most weight in explaining why some villages have better access to public services.

Unpacking State Capacity and Impacts on Service Delivery

Capacity is often deemed a necessary prerequisite for states to translate policy decisions into the provision of public goods and services (Andrews et al. 2017; World Bank 2017). Yet, at least two factors complicate the seemingly straightforward link between greater capacity and improved service delivery. First, features typically associated with higher capacity are not always associated with better service delivery. For example, while a merit- and rule-based bureaucracy may produce better services than a discretionary one, an over-abundance of rules could make it difficult to render expedient decisions that are tailored to local circumstances.

Second, despite rich literatures on the effects of state capacity on various social, economic, and political outcomes (e.g., Andersen et al. 2014; Besley and Persson 2010; Humphreys 2005), there is little consensus on how to measure it. In part, this is because state capacity is a multi-dimensional concept (Hendrix 2010). Moreover, the concept often suffers from “whole nation bias,” or, the tendency to “gravitate toward national level data and units of analysis” (Snyder 2001, p. 94). In reality, state capacity varies extensively across different parts of the same country (Gingerich 2013), with significant implications for quality of life across communities (O’Donnell 1993). These subnational differences in capacity play a significant role in explaining spatial differences in service delivery (Ziblatt 2008).

In the following, we discuss several dimensions of state capacity that may shape service delivery, and how these dimensions may vary across locations and sectors. We argue that a measure of state capacity that can vary across relevant dimensions of capacity, sectors, and space offers the highest degree of concept-measure consistency and should be used to understand how state capacity affects the political geography of service delivery.

Administrative Capacity

The archetypal view on state capacity originates from Weber ([1904–1911] 1978), articulated in his set of essays Economy and Society. Therein, Weber argues that a rational-legal bureaucracy guided by meritocracy, high levels of expertise, and respect for the law was most likely to promote prosperity. These qualities—often collectively referred to as “administrative capacity”—enable bureaucracies to implement policies through competent and skilled state employees who have incentives to pursue their mandates. By contrast, bureaucrats that are rewarded for political loyalty rather than merit devote less effort to effective policy implementation. Similarly, bureaucrats with fewer technical skills may deliver poorer services. But, high levels of administrative capacity typically require high levels of resources and investment.

A large number of measures exist to capture administrative capacity. Since a strong bureaucracy only matters in so far as it actually performs the basic functions of governments, some measures focus on how governments are performing as an indicator of administrative capacity. For example, literacy rates (Soifer 2015), tax collection (Slater 2010), provision of basic health and sanitation services (Enriquez et al. 2017), oversight of a national census (Soifer 2015), and maintenance of cadastral records (D’Arcy and Nistotskaya 2017) have all been used as proxies of administrative capacity. While useful for understanding state performance, such outcome-based measures preclude testing how capacity actually affects outcomes (Fukuyama 2013).

Other measures capture the procedures that govern a bureaucracy—like rule-based decision-making (e.g., the Worldwide Governance Indicators’ Rule of Law) and meritocratic recruitment and career mobility (e.g., Evans and Rauch 1999). Yet, an overemphasis on procedures risks overlooking the possibility that the effect of the same rule may vary across social and political contexts. Further, concepts like “merit” can also be difficult to operationalize in practice if it is not obvious what qualities are most important for delivering a given service.

Adding to measurement challenges, administrative capacity can vary substantially across regions. A highly professionalized bureaucracy located in the state capital may not be able to project authority across distance (Herbst 2000). Moreover, a majority of countries have areas of limited statehood where they cannot fully implement or enforce national policies and regulations (Krasner and Risse 2014). In such settings, states lack “infrastructural power,” or the ability to extend the capabilities of the state across the entire territory that it de-jure administers (Mann 1984; Soifer and vom Hau 2008). Spatial variation can also emerge due to basic differences in staffing across localities. In a study on the provision of public health services across German cities in the early twentieth century, Ziblatt (2008) finds that cities with more fiscal resources and higher staff professionalization deliver more services. Indeed, many areas of policymaking fall under the jurisdictions of local governments, especially as countries continue to embrace decentralization. Thus, it is perhaps not surprising that some have found little correlation at the national level between state capacity and public goods provision (Lee et al. 2014).

Administrative capacity can also vary across government functions. A central tenet of the “islands of effectiveness” literature is that uneven sectoral development can be linked to pockets of administrative capacity within the government (Crook 2010; Leonard 2010). In other words, there may be one or more organizations within government that provide services relatively effectively despite operating in an environment broadly characterized by inefficiency and patronage. For example, Pogoson and Roll (2013) identify two well-functioning organizations in the Nigerian public service despite operating in a country better-known for endemic corruption.

Bureaucratic Autonomy

Bureaucratic autonomy has also been proposed as a fundamental component of good governance (Evans 1995). The concept of bureaucratic autonomy derives from the literature on principal-agent relationships, whereby bureaucratic agencies provide services under the watchful eye of elected principals (Dixit 2002). For autonomous bureaucracies, politicians provide the broad policy goal to bureaucratic agents, who have some freedom in deciding how best to implement policy based on subject-matter expertise and local conditions.

Autonomy is believed to improve service delivery in a few ways. One way is that agents are not detracted from their main task of policy implementation by spending their time reporting to multiple principals who may have different and even conflicting priorities (Hammond and Knott 1996). Using data from India’s National Rural Employment Guarantee Scheme, Gulzar and Pasquale (2017) find that locations in which bureaucrats are accountable to more than one principal perform worse. Secondly, higher autonomy can provide bureaucrats with a greater sense of motivation and the flexibility to respond to service delivery implementation challenges (Rasul and Rogger 2015).

On the other hand, Lipsky (1980) highlights that autonomy empowers bureaucrats to exercise higher levels of discretion to provide services according to their own prerogative rather than the spirit of the relevant public policy. In the contexts of Nigeria and Pakistan, respectively, Rogger (2014) and Callen et al. (2014) have found that political oversight can be beneficial for service delivery because elected politicians, worried about being held accountable for poor services, may exert pressure on bureaucrats that citizens receive services as intended. In sum, while autonomy is a fundamental dimension of state capabilities, its relationship with service delivery is not straightforward.

Personnel Characteristics

While administrative capacity and bureaucratic autonomy emphasize the organizational setting in which public employees operate, the individual characteristics of public employees may also shape service delivery outcomes. While all civil servants enjoy some discretion in policy implementation, front-line service providers, like agricultural extension officers, are the last link in the chain of service provision. As such, they end up deciding who receives extension services and how (Lipsky 1980), with significant implications for welfare of rural households. Individual qualities of local service providers could thus have an outsized impact on service provision, above and beyond formal rules and procedures.

We focus on two characteristics which may play a role in the quality of service provision. First, given that the government—unlike the private sector—often cannot credibly commit to pay employees based on performance, whether or not public sector employees are intrinsically motivated to perform well at their jobs could make a significant difference in whether public sector organizations achieve their missions (Gailmard and Patty 2007; Perry and Hondegheim 2008). One question is whether mission-driven organizations like public bureaucracies are able to recruit and retain employees with a high level of prosocial motivation compared to the private sector (e.g., Banuri and Keefer 2013; Hanna and Wang 2017). For our purposes, the question is less about the differences in motivations between private and public sector personnel, but rather whether differences in intrinsic motivation among public sector personnel influence service delivery outcomes.

Second, Pepinsky et al. (2017) highlight the value of embeddedness for front-line service providers. Service providers who are socially embedded in the communities that they serve may better understand local challenges and better gather information on local solutions. Frequent interactions between service providers and communities can reduce transaction costs and increase trust. Bhavnani and Lee (2018) find that education levels exert little influence on a civil servant’s performance while local ties to the community improve public goods provision in India. Agricultural extension services in particular demand location-specific information on technology, soil fertility, and farming practices, which increases the informational complexity of the task and requires a high level of local knowledge and embeddedness.

State Capacity and Service Delivery in Nepal

The Nepali state has long struggled to project power into rural areas. Although the country has witnessed different forms of government over time, political power and decision-making have consistently been centralized in Kathmandu, with poor penetration into areas beyond the Kathmandu Valley. The country’s difficult and varied terrain has complicated state-building. The country has three main ecological zones, terai (plains), hills, and mountains, each of which pose particular challenges in projecting state power. The terai are on the southern border and are the most fertile areas of the country, and the mountains lie on the northernmost border. In between lie the hills, which serve as the home for the capital of Kathmandu but also of more remote regions in the far east and west of the country.

Projecting statehood is challenging across these diverse areas due to the long, porous border with India, as well as low road density, low population density in the mountains, high travel costs, and the need for local knowledge of the vastly different geographies and contexts across the country. However, the lack of embeddedness of the state in rural society is not solely a product of geography and the technical challenges of state-building in difficult terrain. Ruling classes legitimated themselves through the creation of myths that emphasized their divine right to rule and to subordinate much of Nepali society through caste hierarchies. These myths and caste hierarchies formed the basis of state legitimacy rather than strong territorial control or provision of public services (Riaz and Basu 2007). In other words, neglect of rural areas was long a governing strategy.

Consequently, for much of Nepal’s history, the state provided little in the way of public services in rural areas. Even as recently as 1971, the state relied exclusively on communities to provide education services (Baird 2010). Over the past 30 to 40 years, the state has begun to assume formal responsibility for delivering essential public services in rural areas. However, it has failed to deliver on these responsibilities in large swathes of the country, resulting in significant geographic inequalities. Adult literacy is 83% in Kathmandu Valley compared with 49% in the far western mountains (UNDP 2014). Other measures of welfare, such as stunting and food insecurity, follow a similar pattern (Haslett et al. 2014). Evidence of low levels of state capacity and poor projection of the state into remote areas is especially pronounced in the wake of large-scale disasters, such as the 2015 earthquake (Jones et al. 2014) or the 2010 Dengue fever outbreak (Griffiths et al. 2013).

Economic, spatial, and ethnic inequalities contributed to the outbreak of civil war in 1996 when members of the Communist Party of Nepal-Maoist (CPN-M) attacked a police post in the midwestern part of Nepal (Do and Iyer 2010; Murshed and Gates 2005). Founded in 1994, the CPN-M viewed armed insurrection as a means of achieving its goals of abolishing the monarchy and creating a people’s republic with an elected constituent assembly to draft a new constitution (Do and Iyer 2010). The absence of the state in many rural areas enabled the Maoists to gain rapid control of rural areas in a short span of time. The war ended in 2006 with the signing of the Comprehensive Peace Agreement. The CPN-M party won the 2008 constituent assembly elections and the leader of the party and former insurgent, Pushpa Kamal Dahal, became prime minister. As one indication of the country’s political fragility, Nepal had nine prime ministers between 2008 and 2016. The changes in government contributed substantially to high levels of ministerial turnover and disruptions to policy continuity. For instance, there were seven ministers of agriculture during this period.Footnote 5

As with other policy domains, agricultural policymaking in Nepal long has been centralized—though service delivery often was delegated to deconcentrated units of central line ministries at the district level—and highly politicized. Agricultural service delivery is key to the government’s efforts to regain legitimacy in rural areas through public services. In the absence of a sizeable manufacturing sector, agriculture provides a livelihood for approximately two-thirds of Nepal’s population and contributes one-third to the country’s GDP (USAID 2013). Due to the size of the sector, agriculture can be highly politicized in the country. Farmers’ cooperatives, for example, often include representation from the wings of various political parties.Footnote 6

Nepal has a pluralistic agricultural extension system, with public, private sector, and non-governmental actors. The focus of this paper is on the public agricultural extension system, which predominates in Nepal. Public agricultural extension is overseen by the Ministry of Agricultural Development (MoAD) and executed through deconcentrated district offices (see Fig. 1). In turn, MoAD district offices oversee agricultural service centers at the Ilaka level (sub-district).Footnote 7 Extension agents are based in the service centers and are accountable to District Agricultural Development Officers (DADOs), who manage the deconcentrated district offices (Kyle and Resnick 2017). Although DADOs are formally accountable to MoAD in Kathmandu, weak monitoring gives them wide latitude in deciding how to deploy the resources and staff that they oversee.Footnote 8

Fig. 1
figure 1

Schematic of extension service delivery in Nepal

In theory, all agricultural extension agents are recruited from the national civil service, known as the Public Service Commission (FAO 2010).Footnote 9 In practice, however, Nepal struggles to recruit sufficient civil servants through this mechanism. Therefore, a junior technician position, which does not require a university degree and which can be recruited locally, was created in order to fill staffing gaps.

Agricultural extension services involve trained professionals sharing information with households that pursue a livelihood in the farming, fishing, forestry, or livestock sectors, with the long-term intention of encouraging behavioral change. Extension agents may share, for example, information on higher-yielding varieties of seeds and fertilizers, improved cultivation techniques, natural resource management, price data, opportunities for increasing market access, and provide veterinary medicines, pesticides, and herbicides (see Swanson and Davis 2014). Research from various country contexts suggests that agricultural extension, if properly implemented, can play a critical role in enhancing agricultural productivity growth (Fan and Zhang 2008). In Nepal, where rural food insecurity is high and agricultural productivity is low (GoN 2013), such services could help farmers identify methods for addressing low soil fertility, access new commodity markets, or deal with invasive pests. This is typically done through farm visits, agricultural demonstrations, and community meetings (FAO 2010).

Despite the potential for agricultural extension services to improve rural livelihoods across Nepal, its delivery is weak. On average, agricultural extension officers serve only about 15% of agricultural households nationwide (GoN 2010). Although agents cover a large area, they frequently lack resources to travel and operate with few supplies or infrastructure (Suvedi and McNamara 2012). Consequently, DADOs widely report being understaffed, with 85% reporting a lack of qualified staff to deliver services (Kyle and Resnick 2017). Compounding staff shortages, farmers are geographically dispersed across the country, and Nepal’s poor infrastructure and diverse topographies makes it difficult, time-consuming, and costly to reach them.

Notwithstanding this overall context of low state capacity and weak extension systems, some villages in Nepal, like Barbote introduced earlier, do receive widespread governmental extension services. The following section explores which components of state capacity contribute to this unexpected outcome.

Measuring Service Access and Subnational State Capacity in Nepal

We use two original data sources for the analysis. First, we implemented a nationally representative survey of rural households in Nepal that was fielded in May–July 2016. To draw the survey sample, we randomly selected 75 village development committees (VDCs). Within each sampled VDC, we randomly selected two wards to be our enumeration areas and sampled seven households on average from the population of each selected ward to be interviewed for a total sample of 1054 rural households. Full information on the sampling procedure is available in Appendix A. All outcome variables are drawn from the household survey.Footnote 10

Second, we measure different dimensions of subnational state capacity to deliver agricultural extension services based on a set of structured interviews with 50 (out of 75 total) DADOs from randomly selected districts in Nepal. The interviews collected information on the resources and staff devoted to agriculture extension services in each district, but also asked open-ended questions about how DADOs deploy resources and manage staff. Figure 2 indicates in gray the districts where DADO interviews and the household survey overlap (44 districts).

Fig. 2
figure 2

Location of survey respondents. Note: Districts highlighted in gray indicate areas where the DADO survey and the household survey overlapped

Service Access

We measure our dependent variable, access to agricultural extension services, in three ways. First, we consider whether or not citizens believe that a governmental extension agent serves their area. Even using this broad measure, Fig. 3 shows that access to extension services in Nepal is low, with only 33% of respondents reporting that a governmental agricultural technician serves their area. Second, we look at whether households actually received extension services during the past year. Although one-third of the sample believes that a governmental extension agent serves their area, only 24% of households actually received extension services from any advisory services, governmental, or otherwise, during the past year. Even fewer report receiving advisory services specifically from governmental extension agents (9%). We look at each of these access measures because some households (9%) received extension services but cannot recall the source, so focusing on governmental services alone risks undercounting access.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Service access

State Capacity

The primary interest of the paper is understanding how different dimensions of state capacity—disaggregated by location and sector—influence service delivery (see Table 1). First, we measure the resources that each district can devote to service delivery as the number of agricultural extension workers in the district per farmer.Footnote 11 By this account, capacity in Nepal is remarkably low: on average, each extension worker serves 4421 farmers. By comparison, the average extension worker in neighboring India serves half as many farmers (Kyle and Resnick 2017). However, there is also remarkable variation across districts. In some districts, each extension worker covers closer to 1000 farmers, while in others each is responsible for over 27,000 farmers.Footnote 12

Table 1 State capacity

Second, following Ziblatt (2008), we measure staff professionalization based on the share of extension agents within the district with university degrees. Many districts in Nepal struggle to find staff with sufficient qualifications to serve as extension agents: on average, less than 20% of crop extension agents hold university degrees. The remaining 80% are junior technical officers or junior technical assistants who only have a high school education plus one agricultural course. While they may have access to certain training programs that would theoretically bolster their professionalization, the reality is that such trainings are offered erratically and in differing quality. As the FAO (2010: 36) observes with respect to JTOs/JTAs, “Identification of training needs and impact evaluation of trainings on job performance and on the change in livelihoods of the farming community are seldom carried out.”

Third, we measure bureaucratic autonomy by asking the DADOs whether and how often politicians intervene in their district’s agricultural policy planning. As noted earlier, political involvement in agricultural policymaking tends to be high: “agricultural service delivery through the public sector is starved of resources, is neither demand driven, participatory, nor impact oriented, and is subject to high levels of political interference” (Jones 2010, p. 6). In part, this is due to the agrarian roots of Nepal’s Maoist political parties and their involvement in the formation and organization of farmers’ cooperatives across the country. From our data, 75% of district officials report that politicians interfere frequently in policy planning and implementation.

While administrative capacity and bureaucratic autonomy emphasize the organizational setting in which representatives of the state operate, the qualities and skills of local bureaucrats themselves may contribute to capabilities for policy implementation. Knowledge of local context and communities may enhance DADOs’ abilities to deliver services since farmers’ needs vary with local agroecological conditions like soil conditions, elevation, and moisture availability. Indeed, one of the primary arguments in favor of local control over policy implementation is that it enables local actors to tailor public services to local conditions. Yet, their ability to do so depends on whether or not they have knowledge of local conditions in the first place.

As a proxy for this local knowledge, we ask how long each DADO has worked in the district in his current position and in any previous job position. Due to the prevalence of bureaucratic re-assignments as a means of rewarding (sanctioning) political (dis)loyalty, there is wide variation in the length of years that DADOs have worked in the district. In fact, 70% of surveyed bureaucrats have lived in their assigned districts for less than 2 years at the time of the survey. However, there are also bureaucrats with more years in their assigned districts, and around 16% of respondents have worked in their districts for more than 5 years.Footnote 13 Yet, years in the district could affect service delivery through other channels as well. Length of bureaucratic tenures is sometimes described as one component of the professionalization of the bureaucracy (Evans 1995). More time spent in the district can also enable deeper embeddedness within local communities.

For the same reasons, local knowledge of extension agents can matter as well. Extension agents who understand the local agroecological conditions as well as the languages, customs, and cultures of local communities will be better positioned to deliver useful and accurate information and to gain the trust of farmers. We therefore asked DADOs whether the majority of the extension agents serving in agricultural service centers in their districts are recruited from the district. Thirty-eight percent of DADOs report that the majority of their staff are local.

Finally, as the overseer of agricultural policy implementation in the district, a DADOs’ motivation is important as well. Given that they all have to grapple with limited staff and resources, differences in intrinsic motivation could shape whether and how thoughtfully an individual DADO deploys resources within his district. The concept of intrinsic motivation has a long history, and has featured across economics, the social and behavioral sciences, public administration, and organizational literatures.Footnote 14 At its root, it suggests that employees are strongly motivated to make a major difference in the lives of those they were hired to serve (Paarlberg and Lavigna 2010; Prendergast 2008). Measurements to capture this notion are numerous. Perry’s (1996) public service motivation scale has been one of the most commonly used; it assesses civil servants’ commitment to the public interest, policymaking, social justice, civic duty, compassion, and self-sacrifice. The approach, however, was developed in the USA and international applications show that these constituent measures can vary depending on cultural, historical, and institutional particularities of countries (Vandenabeele and Van de Walle 2008).

Rasul and Rogger (2015) measure intrinsic motivation based on asking bureaucrats which factors originally influenced them to enter the civil service. Those who claim a commitment to the national interest, rather than income, prestige, or other narrow personal benefits, are classified as having more intrinsic motivation. Yet, this assumes that the same factors that motivated a bureaucrat to enter the civil service persist throughout that individual’s tenure, even as job circumstances, supervisors, and postings may change.

Dewett (2007) suggests that intrinsic motivation is reflected by an employee’s creativity and uses supervisors’ rankings of employees’ creativity based their ability to derive “novel and practical work-related ideas.” We draw on the latter conceptualization because it allows for context specificity depending on both the country as well as the type of job, especially given that intrinsic motivation can vary across the tasks and missions of specific sectors (Wright 2007). Specifically, if DADOs are motivated to improve the lives of those rural citizens they were hired to serve, then they should demonstrate some creativity in trying to address their client’s main constraints to improved incomes and poverty reduction.

To capture this, we use an open-ended question that asked the DADO to describe any agricultural development project that he believed would make a difference in their district, if they were given an additional budget of Rp. 5 million (about $47,000 USD) to implement it.Footnote 15 Resource-constrained bureaucrats who are motivated to address the problems of farmers in their district should have at least one idea for what they would want to do for local farmers if given more resources.

We coded their responses into three groups: (0) those that could not come up with any project at all that they thought would contribute to local agricultural development; (1) those that gave a generic answer, perhaps referencing a commodity or a goal (e.g., increase cardamom production), but giving no ideas about how they would do so; and (2) those that offered a discussion of a policy (i.e., what and whom to target), even if still in general terms (e.g., help youth get involved in dairy production). While 38% of DADOs did offer a discussion of a policy during the interview, 27% said that they did not have any ideas for how to spend additional resources in their district.Footnote 16

Do these indicators of capacity within the agricultural sector tend to flow together, or do they exist independently from each other within districts? Figure 4 depicts the correlations between these measures. The correlations indicate that capacity—even within a single sector—is multi-faceted. Indeed, many of the measurements have weak negative correlations. Notably, there is a negative correlation between the number of extension agents per farmer and staff professionalization. This is because of the limited pool of university graduates recruited to work as extension officers: districts that have been able to increase staffing numbers have done so by hiring at the junior technician level, which does not require a university degree (FAO 2010). There are also positive correlations between how long a DADO has served in a district, his motivation, and whether the majority of the staff are local to the district. This makes intuitive sense: highly motivated DADOs with more local embeddedness are the most likely to address staffing shortages by using the local hiring mechanism and taking responsibility for training junior technicians themselves.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Correlations between state capacity indicators

In a low resource environment, building capacity may involve trade-offs: investing in one dimension could mean sacrificing in another. In any case, weak correlations between dimensions suggest that in this context, capacity should not be condensed to a single measure but, rather, that dimensions should be separately measured and tested.

Alternative Explanations

While we are focused on the role of local capacity in shaping service delivery, there are several alternative explanations for why public service provision may vary across rural localities. We discuss two important alternative explanations for variation in rural service delivery. First, a village’s remoteness, beyond the capabilities of the institutions that govern it, may shape local bureaucrats’ ability to provide a village with services. Projecting the power of the state across varied ecological conditions and vast distances is both costly and complex. Roads in particular serve as a connecting link between state and society, and the state often struggles to maintain a physical presence in their absence (Herbst 2000). Remoteness from the state and public services is particularly acute in countries with hilly terrain, where lengthy travel times limit interactions between state institutions and remote populations (Scott 2009). While village remoteness is a significant barrier to public service delivery in rural areas (e.g., Brinkerhoff et al. Forthcoming; Lee et al. 2005), there is still considerable unexplained variation in service access. Overall, a village’s remoteness from agricultural service centers explains less than 10% of the variation in access to extension services across villages in our sample.

In order to measure how far villages are from agricultural extension services, we asked households the time that it takes to travel to their nearest agricultural service center which, as noted earlier, is where extension staff are based. We measure distance in terms of travel times rather than kilometers because, particularly in areas with rough terrain and poor road networks, travel time is a more accurate reflection of the distance. The median respondent in the sample lives 45 min away from an agricultural service center, the average respondent lives 80 min away from an agricultural service center, and about 5% of respondents live more than 3 h away from one. In three of the surveyed villages, none of the respondents in the village knew where the nearest agricultural service center was located, likely an indication that the service center is quite distant. In order to not truncate the data by excluding these villages, we regress travel time to the nearest agricultural service center on distance to the nearest major road. We use this to predict travel times for villages with missing data. Results are robust to excluding these villages as well.Footnote 17

Second, the natural agricultural conditions in one part of the country could affect both the government’s incentive to invest resources into agriculture as well as households’ demand for agricultural services. Consequently, another alternative hypothesis we explore is whether distinct agroecological conditions explain variation in agricultural extension access. This is measured by average annual rainfall, rainfall variability, elevation, squared elevation, and population density.Footnote 18 Rainfall is essential for agricultural productivity while altitude has important implications for soil fertility and pest control. Population density is a measure of land-to-labor ratios and therefore indicates whether there is a comparative advantage for labor intensive production (Chamberlin et al. 2006). We control for both remoteness and agricultural development potential in order to isolate the effects of capacity.Footnote 19

Controls

We also include a variety of other controls, such as district GDP per capita (UNDP 2014) since wealthy areas may be disproportionately deprived of public extension services due to greater availability of private extension options in those areas. In addition, we include the number of conflict-related deaths in the district during the civil war (Do and Iyer 2010). Rural areas that were conflict-afflicted may have been more likely to experience a suspension in agricultural service delivery.

We also include a series of socio-economic control variables likely to affect whether households would be more aware of agricultural extension service availability. These include land size, irrigation, wealth index, remittance, food insecurity, education, and whether the respondent identifies as a member of a disadvantaged group within Nepal, who have faced systematically lower access to governmental services in Nepal throughout its history.Footnote 20 Appendix Table 7 presents summary statistics and discusses measurement of each control variable.

Analysis and Results

In this section, we estimate a series of logit models with a binary dependent variable that codes whether a household believes that a governmental extension agent serves their village, whether a household received extension services (from any source) during the past year, and whether a household received governmental extension services during the past year. All models include the controls discussed above. Table 2 reports our main findings.

Table 2 Effects of capacity and distance on access to extension services

Notably, individual characteristics of the DADOs are significantly associated with higher access to extension services. One additional year in a district is associated with a 4% increase in the predicted probability that a household believes governmental services exist in the village and a 6% increase in the predicted probability that a household receives governmental extension services.Footnote 21 The importance of local connections is reflected in the relationship between hiring a staff that is mostly local. When a majority of extension agents are local, there is a 33% increase in the predicted probability of receiving any extension services. Meanwhile, a DADO being able to describe what he would do with additional resources is associated with a 65% increase in the predicted probability that a household believes governmental extension services are available and a 58% increase in the predicted probability that a household receives extension services from any source, all else equal.

Appendix Table 9 reports results at the village level, and results are consistent to the household-level models reported here. Findings are also broadly consistent when fixed effects by region (Appendix Table 10) and by agroecological zone (Appendix Table 11) are included.

Yet, surprisingly, the organizational settings in which bureaucrats operate are not robustly linked with better services. Greater shares of extension workers with bachelors’ degrees are associated with lower, rather than higher, awareness of whether an extension agent serves the respondent’s village, although the effect size is negligible. Similarly, better staffing ratios and more autonomy are (mostly) negatively linked with service access, though only the relationship between having more staff and knowledge of extension services in the village is significant. This corroborates with the example of the villages of Barbote and Pyang that we introduced in the beginning of the paper. Barbote, despite having a ratio of extension agents to farmer that is half of the ratio of Pyang, receives more than quadruple the level of service access.

One potential explanation for these puzzling patterns is that there is no ideal organizational setting in a country of such low overall capacity. For example, districts with more educated extension agents are also those that have more agents nearing retirement, who are perhaps less motivated to go into the field. Districts with higher staffing levels are those that have hired more junior technicians, who are less educated. There seems to be a constraint on increasing both staffing ratios and staff professionalization, yielding mixed effects on service access. Political interference with policymaking may sometimes have positive effects for rural service access in this context where the dominant political parties are highly engaged with farmers’ groups. Irrespective of the organizational setting, local knowledge and the motivation that DADOs can deploy toward service delivery seems to matter most.

Other explanations for service delivery matter as well. For one, distance significantly reduces access: living an hour further away from the nearest agricultural service center reduces the predicted probability of receiving extension services by 6 percentage points, a 32% increase from the mean. A bit counterintuitively, elevation increases access to services, though this effect diminishes as elevation rises. In the Nepali context, this is likely explained by the historical preference for establishing more agricultural service centers in the hills region, rather than in the mountains or plains (see FAO 2010). Other factors matter as well; namely, more educated households and those in richer districts are more likely to receive services, as are those that receive remittances, and those with larger, irrigated plots. This suggests that these better-off households either have more resources to demand services or a greater awareness of where to locate them.

Placebo Test

Any study of political geography faces identification challenges. An ideal research design would isolate the effects of subnational state capacity from other factors which vary by district. We can control for observable factors which vary by district and shape service delivery. However, unobservables can still confound findings. One way to probe the findings is by conducting placebo tests: specifically, we test whether current capacity has an effect on past service delivery. Future capacity cannot have a causal impact on past outcomes, especially factors like the current DADO’s motivation and time employed in the district, given how often DADOs transfer; however, if relationships are driven by unobservables, apparent counterfactual effects could appear in this test.

Table 3 utilizes data from the Nepal Living Standards Survey (NLSS) III collected in 2010/11. This nationally representative survey asks households whether they received governmental extension services during the past year. Current capacity indicators do not predict past governmental performance, as expected. This lends confidence that district unobservables are not driving results.

Table 3 Placebo tests, effects of current capacity on past service delivery

Overall, these findings suggest that disparate dimensions of state capacity exert differential effects on service delivery. Surprisingly, administrative capacity and bureaucratic autonomy had little overall influence over access to extension services. Instead, DADOs’ time employed in the district, whether their staff are local, and their ability to describe how they would spend additional resources in their district are more influential in explaining service delivery outcomes. Collectively, this suggests that efforts to improve capacity should place more emphasis on reducing excessive use of rotation, hiring local staff, and gaining an understanding of why some DADOs are more motivated than others.

Conclusions

Unpacking state capacity is critical for many developing countries, which strive to deliver traditional services to citizens and to find innovative ways to implement cash transfer programs, scale up pension schemes, design smart subsidies, and collect tax revenue. However, weak state capacity is frequently identified as the culprit for poor program implementation. In turn, capacity building is a major area of investment by the international development community (see Andrews et al. 2017).

While there has been scholarly awareness of the importance of good governance, there have been few attempts to examine whether different components of the concept may exert disparate influences. Consequently, one contribution of this paper is to respond to Fukuyama’s (2013) call for disaggregated measures of capacity that recognize the variation of this concept across functions, levels of government, and regions within countries. By using disaggregated indicators of capacity in the agricultural sector, we identify which aspects of capacity are most likely to increase access to extension services in a country that is often described as a uniformly weak state.

In doing so, we find that simply improving the ratio of extension agents to agricultural workers is insufficient for increasing extension access. Instead, those agricultural bureaucrats employed longer in a district and with greater motivation tend to be associated with greater extension access. This is not to say that more resources and staff education are not needed in this context—it would be hard to argue otherwise in the face of the extremely low staffing levels. Rather, the findings suggest that doing so is ineffective unless local bureaucrats have the skills, knowledge, and motivation to deploy those resources productively.

The findings also contain a hopeful message for service delivery in areas of limited statehood: even when resources are scarce, knowledgeable and motivated bureaucrats can deliver surprisingly high levels of services with scant resources. Where university graduates are scarce, staffing districts with junior technicians—as long as they are local—improves outcomes as these local staff are more embedded in local conditions and communities. Reducing the use of district transfers at both the junior and senior levels would be an inexpensive way to improve service outcomes and encourage greater embeddedness. However, this could mean that the government needs more potent means of sanctioning and rewarding employee performance.

Access to services is especially important in rural Nepal, where there are few private sector alternatives, where agricultural productivity lags, and where the government still needs to rebuild legitimacy after the civil war. Since responsiveness to citizen preferences for services plays a critical role in enhancing state legitimacy in post-conflict states (see Brinkerhoff et al. 2012; Mcloughlin 2015), determining which elements of capacity should be prioritized and reinforced will remain central to the consolidation of Nepal’s still-fragile democracy.