Cliometrica

, Volume 6, Issue 1, pp 1–28 | Cite as

The demographic transition: causes and consequences

Original Paper

Abstract

This paper develops the theoretical foundations and the testable implications of the various mechanisms that have been proposed as possible triggers for the demographic transition. Moreover, it examines the empirical validity of each of the theories and their significance for the understanding of the transition from stagnation to growth. The analysis suggests that the rise in the demand for human capital in the process of development was the main trigger for the decline in fertility and the transition to modern growth

Keywords

Demographic transition Gender gap Human capital Fertility Mortality Unified growth theory 

JEL Classification

O10 J1 

References

  1. Angrist JD, Lavy V, Schlosser A (2010) Multiple experiments for the causal link between the quantity and quality of children. J Labor Econ 28(4):773–824Google Scholar
  2. Becker GS (1960) An economic analysis of fertility. In: Becker GS (eds) Demographic and economic change in developed countries. Princeton University Press, Princeton, pp 209–231Google Scholar
  3. Becker GS (1981) A treatise on the family. Harvard University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  4. Becker GS, Lewis HG (1973) On the interaction between the quantity and quality of children. J Polit Econ 81(2, Part II):S279–S288CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Becker GS, Murphy KM, Tamura R (1990) Human capital, fertility, and economic growth. J Polit Econ 98(5):S12–S37CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Becker SO, Cinnirella F, Woessmann L (2009) The trade-off between fertility and education: evidence from before the demographic transition. CESifo Working Paper No. 2775Google Scholar
  7. Becker SO, Woessmann L (2009) Was weber wrong? A human capital theory of protestant economic history. Q J Econ 124(2):531–596CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Black SE, Devereux PJ, Salvanes KG (2005) The more the merrier? The effect of family size and birth order on children’s education. Q J Econ 120(2):669–700Google Scholar
  9. Bleakley H, Lange F (2009) Chronic disease burden and the interaction of education, fertility, and growth. Rev Econ Stat 91(1):52–65CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Boldrin M, Jones LE (2002) Mortality, fertility, and saving in a Malthusian economy. Rev Econ Dyn 5(4):775–814CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Botticini M, Eckstein Z (2005) Jewish occupational selection: education, restrictions, or minorities? J Econ Hist 65(4):922–948CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Brown JC, Guinnane TW (2007) Regions and time in the European fertility transition: problems in the Princeton project’s statistical methodology. Econ Hist Rev 60(3):574–595CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Caldwell JC (1976) Toward a restatement of demographic transition theory. Popul Dev Rev 2(3-4):321–366CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Chesnais J (1992) The demographic transition: stages, patterns, and economic implications. Clarendon Press, OxfordGoogle Scholar
  15. Cipolla CM (1969) Literacy and development in the west. Harmondsworth, MiddlesexGoogle Scholar
  16. Doepke M (2004) Accounting for fertility decline during the transition to growth. J Econ Growth 9(3):347–383CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Doepke M (2005) Child mortality and fertility decline: does the Barro-Becker model fit the facts? J Popul Econ 18(2):337–366CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Eckstein Z, Mira P, Wolpin K (1999) A quantitative analysis of Swedish fertility dynamics: 1751–1990. Rev Econ Dyn 2(1):137–165CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Fernández-Villaverde J (2001) Was Malthus right? Economic growth and population dynamics. Working paper, Department of Economics, University of PennsylvaniaGoogle Scholar
  20. Flora P, Kraus F, Pfenning W (1983) State economy and society in Western Europe 1815–1975, vol 1. Palgrave Macmillan, LondonGoogle Scholar
  21. Frankel JA, Romer D (1999) Does trade cause growth? Am Econ Rev 89(3):379–399CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Galor O (2005) From stagnation to growth: unified growth theory, handbook of economic growth, vol IA. Elsevier North-Holland, AmsterdamGoogle Scholar
  23. Galor O (2010) The 2008 Lawrence R. Klein lecture-comparative economic development: insights from unified growth theory. Int Econ Rev 51(1):1–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Galor O, Michalopoulos S (2006) The evolution of entrepreneurial spirit and the process of development. Working paper, Department of Economics, Brown UniversityGoogle Scholar
  25. Galor O, Moav O (2002) Natural selection and the origin of rconomic growth. Q J Econ 117(4):1133–1191CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Galor O, Moav O (2004) From physical to human capital accumulation: inequality and the process of development. Rev Econ Stud 71(4):1001–1026CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Galor O, Mountford A (2006) Trade and the great divergence: the family connection. Am Econ Rev 96(2):299–303CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Galor O, Mountford A (2008) Trading population for productivity: theory and evidence. Rev Econ Stud 75(4):1143–1179CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Galor O, Weil DN (1996) The gender gap, fertility, and growth. Am Econ Rev 86(3):374–387Google Scholar
  30. Galor O, Weil DN (1999) From Malthusian stagnation to modern growth. Am Econ Rev 89(2):150–154CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Galor O, Weil DN (2000) Population, technology, and growth: from Malthusian stagnation to the demographic transition and beyond. Am Econ Rev 90(4):806–828CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Goldin C (1990) Understanding the gender gap: an economic history of American women. Oxford University Press, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  33. Greenwood J, Seshadri A (2002) The US demographic transition. Am Econ Rev 92(2):153–159CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Greenwood J, Seshadri A, Vandenbroucke G (2005) The baby boom and baby bust. Am Econ Rev 95(1):183–207CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Guinnane TW, Okun BS, Trussell J (1994) What do we know about the timing of fertility transitions in Europe? Demography 31(1):1–20CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Hanushek EA (1992) The trade-off between child quantity and quality. J Polit Econ 100(1):84–117CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Hazan M (2009) Longevity and lifetime labor supply: evidence and implications. Econometrica 77(6):1829–1863CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Hazan M, Zoabi H (2006) Does longevity cause growth? A theoretical critique. J Econ Growth 11(4):363–376CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Heckman JJ, Walker JR (1990) The relationship between wages and income and the timing and spacing of births: evidence from Swedish longitudinal data. Econometrica 58(6):1411–1441CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Hernandez DJ (2000) Trends in the well being of America’s children and youth. U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, WashingtonGoogle Scholar
  41. Herzer D, Strulik H, Vollmer S (2010) The long-run determinants of fertility: one century of demographic change 1900–1999. Working paper, University of Hannover, HannoverGoogle Scholar
  42. Hindle S (2004) On the Parish: the micro-politics of poor relief in rural England c. 1550–1750. Clarendon Press, OxfordGoogle Scholar
  43. Jones LE, Tertilt M (2006) An economic history of fertility in the US: 1826–1960. NBER working paper No. 12796Google Scholar
  44. Kalemli-Ozcan S (2002) Does the mortality decline promote economic growth?. J Econ Growth 7(4):411–439CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Klemp MPB, Weisdorf JL (2010) The child quantity-quality trade-off: evidence from the population history of England. Mimeo, Department of Economics, University of CopenhagenGoogle Scholar
  46. Lagerlöf N-P (2003) Gender equality and long-run growth. J Econ Growth 8(4):403–426CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Lehr CS (2009) Evidence on the demographic transition. Rev Econ Stat 91(4):871–887CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Li H, Zhang J, Zhu Y (2008) The quantity-quality trade-off of children in a developing country: identification using Chinese twins. Demography 45(1):223–243CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Maddison A (2001) The world economy: a millennial perspective. OECD, ParisGoogle Scholar
  50. Maddison A (2008) The west and the rest in the world economy: 1000–2030. World Econ 9(4):75–99Google Scholar
  51. Murphy TE (2009) Old habits die hard (sometimes): what can Département heterogeneity tell us about the French fertility decline? Technical report, MIMEOGoogle Scholar
  52. Murtin F (2009) On the demographic transition. OECDGoogle Scholar
  53. Neher PA (1971) Peasants, procreation, and pensions. Am Econ Rev 61(3):380–389Google Scholar
  54. Pelling M, Smith RM (1991) Life, death and the elderly: historical perspectives. Routledge, LondonGoogle Scholar
  55. Reher DS (2004) The demographic transition revisited as a global process. Popul Space Place 10:19–42CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  56. Rosenzweig MR, Wolpin KI (1980) Testing the quantity-quality fertility model: the use of twins as a natural experiment. Econometrica 48(1):227–240CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  57. Rosenzweig MR, Zhang J (2009) Do population control policies induce more human capital investment? Twins, birth weight and china’s “one-child” policy. Rev Econ Stud 76(3):1149–1174CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  58. Schultz TP (1985) Changing world prices, women’s wages, and the fertility transition: Sweden, 1860-1910. J Polit Econ 93(6):1126–1154CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  59. Schultz TP (1997) Demand for children in low income countries. Handb Popul Fam Econ 1:349–430CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  60. Sheshinski E (2009) Uncertain longevity and investment in educationGoogle Scholar
  61. U.S. Bureau of the Census (1975) Historical statistics of the United States: colonial times to 1970, part 1, Series D 830–844, p172Google Scholar
  62. Wrigley EA, Schofield R (1981) The population history of England, 1541–1871: a reconstruction. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  63. Young A (2005) The gift of the dying: the tragedy of AIDS and the welfare of future African generations*. Q J Econ 120(2):423–466Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer-Verlag 2011

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of EconomicsBrown UniversityProvidenceUSA

Personalised recommendations