Criminal Law and Philosophy

, Volume 3, Issue 3, pp 261–269 | Cite as

A Political Theory of Blackmail: A Reply to Professor Dripps

Original Paper

Abstract

This essay was originally presented at the Rutgers Institute for Law and Philosophy as part of the Symposium on The Evolution of Criminal Law Theory. It is a Reply to Professor Donald Dripps’ politically-based justification for blackmail’s prohibition. Under Dripps’ account, by exacting payment from the victim blackmail is an impermissible form of private punishment that usurps the state’s public monopoly on law enforcement. This essay demonstrates that Dripps’ account is either under-inclusive or over-inclusive or both. Dripps’ account is applied to a number of the standard blackmail scenarios by which theories of blackmail are typically assessed. Dripps’ account is under-inclusive by failing to treat as blackmail Victim-Welcomed Blackmail, Non-Monetary Blackmail, Rebuffed Blackmail, and Non-Informational Blackmail which the law considers as blackmail. And it is over-inclusive by treating as blackmail Victim-Initiated Exchange and Unconditional Disclosure which the law does not recognize as blackmail.

Keywords

Criminal law Punishment Blackmail Moral theory of punishment 

References

  1. Berman, M. N. (1998). The evidentiary theory of blackmail: Taking motives seriously. The University of Chicago Law Review, University of Chicago, Law School, 65, 795–878. doi:10.2307/1600300.
  2. Brown, J. G. (1993). Blackmail as private justice. University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 141, 1935–1974. doi:10.2307/3312579.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Christopher, K. H. (2005). Toward a resolution of blackmail’s second paradox. Arizona State Law Journal, 37, 1127–1151.Google Scholar
  4. DeLong, S. W. (1993). Blackmailers, bribe takers, and the second paradox. University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 141, 1663–1693. doi:10.2307/3312571.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Dripps, D.A. (2008, November). The priority of politics and procedure over perfectionism in penal law, OR, Blackmail in perspective. Paper Delivered at The Evolution of Criminal law Theory Conference, Rutgers Institute for Law and Philosophy, New Jersey.Google Scholar
  6. Ginsburg, D. H., & Shechtman, P. (1993). Blackmail: An economic analysis of the law. University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 141, 1849–1876. doi:10.2307/3312576.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Katz, L. (1993). Blackmail and other forms of arm-twisting. University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 141, 1567–1614. doi:10.2307/3312568.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Katz, L. (1996). Ill-gotten gains: Evasion, blackmail, fraud, and kindred puzzles of the law. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  9. Landes, W. N., & Posner, R. A. (1975). The private enforcement of law. The Journal of Legal Studies, 4, 1–46. doi:10.1086/467524.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Levy, K. (2007). The solution to the real blackmail paradox: The common link between blackmail and other criminal threats. Connecticut Law Review, 39, 1051–1096.Google Scholar
  11. Lindgren, J. (1984a). Unraveling the paradox of blackmail. Columbia Law Review, 84, 670–717. doi:10.2307/1122502.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Lindgren, J. (1984b). More blackmail ink: A critique of blackmail, inc., Epstein’s theory of blackmail. Connecticut Law Review, 16, 909–923.Google Scholar
  13. Shavell, S. (1993). An economic analysis of threats and their illegality: Blackmail, extortion, and robbery. University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 141, 1877–1903. doi:10.2307/3312577.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Smith, H. E. (1998). The harm in blackmail. Northwestern University Law Review, 92, 861–915.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media B.V. 2009

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.The University of Tulsa College of LawTulsaUSA

Personalised recommendations