How the court made a federation of the EU

Article

Abstract

We analyze the European institutional integration that took place in the 1950s and 1960s as a two-stage process. Firstly, an explicitly political project aims at establishing a European political community. The project is abandoned in the mid-1950s and political integration stops. At that time, the institutions of the Union take the form of a confederation. In a second stage, because of the failure of the European political community, a legal process of integration driven by the European Court of Justice takes place. This second stage of unification is more centralizing and in effect leads to a federalization of the European institutional structure. The transformation of the political structure of the European Union thus appears to result from the actions and decisions of a legal entity, the European Court of Justice.

Keywords

European Union Agency theory European Court of Justice Federation Centralization History of the EU 

JEL Codes

D72 H11 K10 N41 

Notes

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank the three anonymous referees for their comments and suggestions on the first version of this article. An earlier version was presented at the 2006 European Public Choice Society meetings in Turku.

References

  1. Alter, K. (1998). Who are the ‘masters of the treaty’? European governments and the European Court of Justice. International Organization, 52(1), 121–147.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Bebr, G. (1953). The European Coal and Steel Community: A political and legal innovation. Yale Law Journal, 63(1), 1–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Buchanan, J. (1996). Europe as a social reality. Constitutional Political Economy, 7(4), 253–256.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Delaney, E. (2003). The division of competencies demands a revised judicial system. Mimeo. Paper presented at the ‘Governing together in the new Europe’ Conference.Google Scholar
  5. Draft Treaty establishing a European Political Community. (1953). Mimeo.Google Scholar
  6. Forsyth, M. (1967). The political objective of European integration. International Affairs, 43(3), 483–497.Google Scholar
  7. Frey, B. (1996). A directly democratic and federal Europe. Constitutional Political Economy, 7(4), 267–279.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Garrett, G., Kelemen, D., & Schulz, H. (1998). The European Court of Justice, national governments, and legal integration in the European Union. International Organization, 52(1), 149–176.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Holcombe, R. (1991). Constitutions as constraints: A case-study of three American constitutions. Constitutional Political Economy, 2(4), 303–328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Holcombe, R. (1996). Vibert’s vision: Constitutional theory in search of a constitution. Constitutional Political Economy, 7(4), 281–291.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Holcombe, R. (1998). Constitution theory and the constitutional history of colonial America. The Independent Review, 3(4), 21–36.Google Scholar
  12. Issing, O. (2000). Europe: Common money-political union? Economic Affairs, 20(1), 33–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Josselin, J.-M., & Marciano, A. (2000). Displacing your principal. Two historical case studies of some interest for the constitutional future of Europe. European Journal of Law and Economics, 10(3), 217–223.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Josselin, J.-M., & Marciano, A. (2004). Federalism and subsidiarity, in national and international contexts. In J. Backhaus & R. Wagner (Eds.), The handbook of public finance (pp. 477–520). Boston, MA: Kluwer.Google Scholar
  15. Josselin, J.-M., & Marciano, A. (2005). Administrative law and economics. In J. Backhaus (Ed.), The Elgar companion to law and economics (2nd ed., pp. 239–245). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
  16. Karp, B. (1954). The draft constitution for a European Political Community. International Organization, 8(2), 181–202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Kitzinger, U. (1960). Europe: The six and the seven. International Organization, 14(1), 20–36.Google Scholar
  18. Kunz, J. (1953). Treaty establishing the European Defense Community. The American Journal of Comparative Law, 47(2), 275–282.Google Scholar
  19. Koopmans, T. (1991). The birth of European law at the crossroads of legal traditions. The American Journal of Comparative Law, 39(3), 493–507.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Lagrange, M. (1961). The role of the Court of Justice of the European Communities as seen through its case law. Law and Contemporary Problems, 26(3), 400–417.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Lagrange, M. (1964). Speech delivered by Advocate General Maurice Lagrange at the formal sitting of the Court on 8 October 1964, http://www.ena.lu/mce.cfm.
  22. Lagrange, M. (1967). The Court of Justice as a factor in European Integration. The American Journal of Comparative Law, 15(4), 709–725.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Laurent, P.-H. (1970). Paul-Henri Spaak and the diplomatic origins of the common market. Political Science Quarterly, 5(3), 373–396.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Maes, I. (2006). The ascent of the European Commission as an actor in the monetary integration process in the 1960s. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 53(2), 222–241.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Mancini, F. (1991). The making of a constitution for Europe. In R. Keohane & S. Hoffmann (Eds.), The new European community (pp. 177–194). Boulder, CO: Westview.Google Scholar
  26. Mancini, F., & Keeling, D. (1994). Democracy and the European Court of Justice. The Modern Law Review, 57(2), 175–190.Google Scholar
  27. Marshall, G. (1947). The Marshall Plan Speech. Harvard: 5 June 1947, http://www.nato.int/docu/speech/1947/s470605a_e.htm.
  28. Monnet, J. (1976). Mémoires. Paris, France: Fayard.Google Scholar
  29. Mueller, D. (1996). Constitutional quandaries in Europe. Constitutional Political Economy, 7(4), 293–302.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Mueller, D. (2002). Constitutional issues regarding European Union expansion. In B. Steunenberg (Ed.), Widening the European Union: The politics of institutional change and reform (pp. 41–57). London, UK: Routledge.Google Scholar
  31. Mueller, D. (2005a). Constitutional political economy in the European Union. Public Choice, 124(1–2), 57–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Mueller, D. (2005b). Constitution making: The European way. In G. Brennan (Ed.), Coercive power and its allocation in the emergent Europe (pp. 27–45). New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  33. Pitarakis, J.-Y., & Tridimas, G. (2003). Joint dynamics of legal and economic integration in the European Union. European Journal of Law and Economics, 16(3), 357–368.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Salmon, P. (2003). Accounting for centralization in the European Union: Niskanen, Monnet or Thatcher? In A. Marciano & J.-M. Josselin (Eds.), From economic to legal competition. New perspectives on law and institutions in Europe (pp. 165–192). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
  35. Schermers, H. (1974). The European Court of Justice: Promoter of European integration. The American Journal of Comparative Law, 22(3), 444–464.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Schmidtchen, D., & Cooter, R. (Eds.) (1997). Constitutional law and the European Union. Aldershot, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
  37. Schuman, R. (1950). Schuman’s radio announcement of a French-German pool for coal and steel. Declaration of 9 May 1950, http://www.eu-history.leidenuniv.nl/index.php3?m=10&c=29.
  38. Spaak, P.-H. (1953). Speech made when handing over the draft statute of the European Political Community to the six ministers for foreign affairs on Monday, March 9, 1953 in Draft Treaty Embodying The Statute Of The European Community. Information and Official Documents Published by the Secretariat of The Constitutional Committee, Paris, pp. 147–154.Google Scholar
  39. Stone Sweet, A., & Caporaso, J. (1998a). La cour de justice et l’intégration européenne. Revue Française De Science Politique, 48, 195–244.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Stone Sweet, A., & Caporaso, J. (1998b). The European Court of Justice and the national courts: A statistical analysis of preliminary reference. Journal of European Public Policy, 5, 66–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Tridimas, G., & Tridimas, T. (2004). National courts and the European Court of Justice: A public choice analysis of the preliminary procedure. International Review of Law and Economics, 24(2), 125–145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Tullock, G. (1965). Constitutional mythology. The New Individualist Review, 3, 13–17.Google Scholar
  43. Vaubel, R. (1996). The constitutional future of the European Union. Constitutional Political Economy, 7(4), 317–324.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Vaubel, R. (1997). The constitutional reform of the European Union. European Economic Review, 41(3–5), 443–450.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Ventotene Memorandum (1941). http://www.ellopos.net/politics/ventotene.htm.
  46. Voigt, S. (2003). Iudex calculat: The ECJ’s quest for power. Jahrbuch für Neue Politische Ökonomie, 22, 77–101.Google Scholar
  47. Voigt, S., & Salzberger, E. (2002). Choosing not to choose: When politicians choose to delegate powers. Kyklos, 55(2), 289–310.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Weiler, J. (1991). The transformation of Europe. Yale Law Journal, 100, 2403–2483.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science + Business Media, LLC 2006

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Université de Rennes 1 and Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique—CREM (UMR CNRS 6211), Faculté des Sciences EconomiquesRennes cedexFrance
  2. 2.Université de Reims Champagne Ardenne (OMI-EDJ) and Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique—EconomiX (UMR CNRS 7166), Faculté des Sciences EconomiquesReims cedexFrance

Personalised recommendations