Ecological Research

, Volume 21, Issue 3, pp 328–333 | Cite as

Learning to live in a global commons: socioeconomic challenges for a sustainable environment

Special Feature Theoretical ecology

Abstract

Ecologists, economists and other social scientists have much incentive for interaction. First of all, ecological systems and socioeconomic systems are linked in their dynamics, and these linkages are key to coupling environmental protection and economic growth. Beyond this, however, are the obvious similarities in how ecological systems and socioeconomic systems function, and the common theoretical challenges in understanding their dynamics. This should not be surprising. Socioeconomic systems are in fact ecological systems, in which the familiar ecological phenomena of exploitation, cooperation and parasitism all can be identified as key features. Or, viewed from the opposite perspective, ecological systems are economic systems, in which competition for resources is key, and in which an evolutionary process shapes the individual agents to a distribution of specialization of function that leads to the emergence of flows and functionalities at higher levels of organization. Most fundamentally, ecological and socioeconomic systems alike are complex adaptive systems, in which patterns at the macroscopic level emerge from interactions and selection mechanisms mediated at many levels of organization, from individual agents to collectives to whole systems and even above. In such complex adaptive systems, robustness must be understood as emergent from selection processes operating at these many different levels, and the inherent nonlinearities can trigger sudden shifts in regimes that, in the case of the biosphere, can have major consequences for humanity. This lecture will explore the complex adaptive nature of ecosystems, and the implications for the robustness of ecosystem services on which we depend, and in particular examine the conditions under which cooperative behavior emerges. It will then turn attention to the socioeconomic systems in which environmental management is based, and ask what lessons can be learned from our examination of natural systems, and how we can modify social norms to achieve global cooperation in managing our common future. Of special interest will be issues of intragenerational and intergenerational equity, and the importance of various forms of discounting.

References

  1. Aoki K, Ihara Y, Feldman MW (2006) Conditions for the spread of culturally transmitted costly punishment of sib mating. In: Brown M (ed) Towards a scientific concept of culture (in press)Google Scholar
  2. Axelrod R (1997) The complexity of cooperation. Princeton University Press, PrincetonGoogle Scholar
  3. Bowles S, Gintis H (2004) The evolution of strong reciprocity: cooperation in heterogeneous populations. Theor Popul Biol 65:17–28PubMedCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Boyd R, Richerson PJ (1996) Why culture is common, but cultural evolution is rare. In: Runciman WG, Smith JM, Dunbar RIM (eds) Evolution of social behavior patterns in primates and man. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 77–93Google Scholar
  5. Cavalli-Sforza LL, Feldman MW (2003) The application of molecular genetic approaches to the study of human evolution. Nat Genet 33(Suppl):266–275PubMedCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Chao D, Levin SA (1999) A simulation of herding behavior: the emergence of large-scale phenomena from local interactions. In: Ruan S, Wolkowicz GSK, Wu J (eds) Differential equations with applications to biology. American Mathematical Society, Providence, pp 81–95Google Scholar
  7. Couzin ID, Krause J, Franks NR, Levin SA (2005) Effective leadership and decision making in animal groups on the move. Nature 433:513–516PubMedCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Dieckmann U (1997) Can adaptive dynamics invade? Trends Ecol Evol 12:128–131CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Dieckmann U, Metz JAJ (eds) (2005) Elements of adaptive dynamics. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  10. Durrett RT, Levin SA (1998) Spatial aspects of interspecific competition. Theor Popul Biol 53:30–43PubMedCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Durrett R, Levin SA (2005) Can stable social groups be maintained by homophilous imitation alone? J Econ Behav Organ 57:267–286CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Ehrlich PR, Levin SA (2005) The evolution of norms. PLoS Biology 3:943–948CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Eshel I (1983) Evolutionary and continuous stability. J Theor Biol 103:99–111CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Fehr E, Gächter S (2002) Altruistic punishment in humans. Nature 415:137–140PubMedCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Fehr E, Fischbacher U, Gachter S (2002) Strong reciprocity, human cooperation and the enforcement of social norms. Hum Nat 13:1–25Google Scholar
  16. Fisher RA (1930) The genetical theory of natural selection. Clarendon Press, OxfordGoogle Scholar
  17. Gould SJ, Lewontin RC (1979) The spandrels of San Marco and the Panglossian paradigm: a critique of the adaptationist programme. Proc R Soc Lond B 205:581–598PubMedCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Hamilton WD (1964) The genetical evolution of social behavior: I and II. J Theor Biol 7:1–52PubMedCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Iwasa Y, Levin SA (1995) The timing of life history events. J Theor Biol 172:33–42CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Iwasa Y, Nakamaru M, Levin SA (1998) Allelopathy of bacteria in a lattice population: competition between colicin-sensitive and colicin-producing strains. Evol Ecol 12:785–802CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Kerr B, Riley MA, Feldman MW, Bohannan BJM (2002) Local dispersal promotes biodiversity in a real-life game of rock-paper-scissors. Nature 418:171–174PubMedCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Kinzig AP, Harte J (1998) Selection of micro-organisms in a spatially explicit environment and implications for plant access to nitrogen. J Ecol 86:841–853CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Klausmeier CA, Litchman E, Daufresne T, Levin SA (2004a) Optimal nitrogen-to-phosphorus stoichiometry of phytoplankton. Nature 429:171–174CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Klausmeier CA, Litchman E, Levin SA (2004b) Phytoplankton growth and stoichiometry under multiple nutrient limitation. Limnol Oceanogr 49:1463–1470CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Klopfer E (1997) Evolution of intermediate exploitation rates in exploiter-victim systems. University of Wisconsin, MadisonGoogle Scholar
  26. Levin SA (1999) Fragile dominion: complexity and the commons. Perseus Books, ReadingGoogle Scholar
  27. Levin SA, Muller-Landau HC (2000) The evolution of dispersal and seed size in plant communities. Evol Ecol Res 2:409–435Google Scholar
  28. Lewontin RC (1961) Evolution and the theory of games. J Theor Biol 1:382–403PubMedCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Livnat A, Pacala SW, Levin SA (2005) The evolution of intergenerational discounting in offspring quality. Am Nat 165:311–321PubMedCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Ludwig D, Levin SA (1991) Evolutionary stability of plant communities and the maintenance of multiple dispersal types. Theor Popul Biol 40:285–307 Erratum: 240 285–307Google Scholar
  31. Maynard Smith J (1982) Evolution and the theory of games. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  32. Maynard Smith J, Price GR (1973) The logic of animal conflict. Nature 246:15–18CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Miller JH (1996) The coevolution of automata in the repeated prisoner’s dilemma. J Econ Behav Organ 29:87–112CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Nakamaru M, Iwasa Y (2005) The evolution of altruism by costly punishment in the lattice structured population: score-dependent viability versus score-dependent fertility. Evol Ecol Res 7:853–870Google Scholar
  35. Nakamaru M, Levin SA (2004) Spread of two linked social norms on complex interaction networks. J Theor Biol 230:57–64PubMedCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Nowak MA, Bonhoeffer S, May RM (1994) Spatial games and the maintenance of cooperation. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 91:4877–4881PubMedCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Slobodkin LB, Rapoport A (1974) An optimal strategy of evolution. Q Rev Biol 49:181–200PubMedCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Tilman D (1994) Competition and biodiversity in spatially structured habitats. Ecology 75:2–16CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. West GB, Brown JH, Enquist BJ (1997) A general model for the origin of allometric scaling laws in biology. Science 276:122–126PubMedCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Zea-Cabrera E, Iwasa Y, Levin S, Rodriguez-Iturbe I (2006) Tragedy of the commons in plant water use. Water Resour Res (in press)Google Scholar

Copyright information

© The Ecological Society of Japan 2006

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of Ecology and Evolutionary BiologyPrinceton UniversityPrincetonUSA

Personalised recommendations