Journal of Risk and Uncertainty

, Volume 46, Issue 1, pp 27–50 | Cite as

Life expectancy as a constructed belief: Evidence of a live-to or die-by framing effect

  • John W. Payne
  • Namika Sagara
  • Suzanne B. Shu
  • Kirstin C. Appelt
  • Eric J. Johnson
Article

Abstract

Life expectations are essential inputs for many important personal decisions. We propose that longevity beliefs are responses constructed at the time of judgment, subject to irrelevant task and context factors, and leading to predictable biases. Specifically, we examine whether life expectancy is affected by the framing of expectations questions as either live-to or die-by, as well as by factors that actually affect longevity such as age, gender, and self-reported health. We find that individuals in a live-to frame report significantly higher chances of being alive at ages 55 through 95 than people in a corresponding die-by frame. Estimated mean life expectancies across three studies and 2300 respondents were 7.38 to 9.17 years longer when solicited in a live-to frame. We are additionally able to show how this framing works on a process level and how it affects preference for life annuities. Implications for models of financial decision making are discussed.

Keywords

Life Expectancy Framing Effects Judgment Annuities 

JEL Classification

D03 – Behavioral Economics D84 – Expectations 

References

  1. Angeletos, G., Laibson, D., Repetto, A., Tobacman, J., & Weinberg, S. (2001). The hyperbolic consumption model: Calibration, simulation, and empirical evaluation. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15(3), 47–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Brenner, L., Koehler, D. J., & Rottenstreich, Y. (2002). Remarks on support theory: Recent advances and future directions. In T. Gilovich, D. Griffin, & D. Kahneman (Eds.), Heuristics and biases: The psychology of intuitive judgment (pp. 489–509). New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Brown, J.R., Kapteyn, A., & Mitchell, O.S. (2011). Framing effects and expected social security claiming behavior. NBER Working Paper 17018.Google Scholar
  4. Brown, J. R., Kling, J. R., Mullainathan, S., & Wrobel, M. V. (2008). Why don’t people insure late-life consumption? A framing explanation of the under-annuitization puzzle. American Economic Review, 98(2), 304–309.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Browning, M., & Crossley, T. F. (2001). The life-cycle model of consumption and saving. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15(3), 3–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Davidoff, T., Brown, J. R., & Diamond, P. (2005). Annuities and individual welfare. American Economic Review, 95, 1573–1590.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. De Martino, B., Kumaran, D., Seymour, B., & Dolan, R. J. (2006). Frames, biases, and rational decision-making in the human brain. Science, 313, 684–687.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Elder, T. E. (2007). Subjective survival probabilities in the health and retirement study: Systematic biases and predictive validity. Working Paper 2007–159, Michigan Retirement Research Center.Google Scholar
  9. Fischhoff, B., Parker, A., Bruine de Bruin, W., Downs, J., Palmgren, C., Dawes, R., & Manski, C. (2000). Teen expectations for significant life events. Public Opinion Quarterly, 64, 189–205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Goodman, B., & Heller, M. (2006). Annuities: Now, later, never? TIAA-CREF White Paper.Google Scholar
  11. Hardisty, D. J., Johnson, E. J., & Weber, E. U. (2010). A dirty word or a dirty world? Attribute framing, political affiliation, and query theory. Psychological Science, 21(1), 86–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Hu, H.T., & Odean, T. (2011). Paying for old age. New York Times 2/25/2011.Google Scholar
  13. Hurd, M. D. (2009). Subjective probabilities in household surveys. Annual Review of Economics, 1, 543–562.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Johnson, E. J., Häubl, G., & Keinan, A. (2007). Aspects of endowment: A query theory of value construction. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition, 33(3), 461–474.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263–291.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Keren, G. (2011). On the definition and possible underpinnings of framing effects: A brief review and a critical evaluation. In G. Keren (Ed.), Perspectives on framing. New York: Psychology Press.Google Scholar
  17. Ludwig, A., & Zimper, A. (2007). A parsimonious model of subjective life expectancy. Working paper 154–2007, University of Mannheim Research Institute for the Economics of Aging.Google Scholar
  18. Manski, C. (2004). Measuring expectations. Econometrica, 72(5), 1329–1376.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Mirowsky, J. (1999). Subjective life expectancy in the US: Correspondence to actuarial estimates by age, sex, and race. Social Science & Medicine, 49, 967–979.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Payne, J. W., Bettman, J. R., & Schkade, D. A. (1999). Measuring constructed preferences: Towards a building code. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 19, 243–270.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Perozek, M. (2008). Using subjective expectations to forecast longevity: Do survey respondents know something we don’t know? Demography, 45, 95–113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Preacher, K. J., & Hayes, A. F. (2008). Asymptotic and resampling strategies for assessing and comparing indirect effects in multiple mediator models. Behavior Research Methods, 40, 879–891.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Puri, M., & Robinson, D. T. (2007). Optimism and economic choice. Journal of Financial Economics, 86, 71–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Schultz, E. (2010). Pensions: The lump-sum gamble. November 27: The Wall Street Journal.Google Scholar
  25. Thaler, R. H., & Sunstein, C. R. (2008). Nudge: improving decisions about health, wealth and happiness. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  26. Tversky, A., & Koehler, D. J. (1994). Support theory: A nonextensional representation of probability judgment. Psychological Review, 101, 547–567.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Van Solinge, H., & Henkens, K. (2009). Living longer, working longer? The impact of subjective life expectancy on retirement intentions and behaviour. European Journal of Public Health, 20, 47–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Viscusi, W. K., & Hakes, J. K. (2003). Risk ratings that do not measure probabilities. Journal of Risk Research, 6, 23–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Weber, E. U., Johnson, E. J., Milch, K. F., Chang, H., Brodscholl, J. C., & Goldstein, D. G. (2007). Asymmetric discounting in intertemporal choice: A query theory account. Psychological Science, 18(6), 516–523.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Weller, J., Dieckmann, N. F., Tusler, M., Mertz, C. K., & Peters, E. (2012). Development and testing of an abbreviated numeracy scale: A rasch analysis approach. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making. doi:10.1002/bdm.1751.
  31. Yaari, M. E. (1965). Uncertain lifetime, life insurance, and the theory of the consumer. Review of Economic Studies, 32, 137–150.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Zhao, X., Lynch, Jr., J. G., & Chen, Q. (2010). Reconsidering Baron and Kenny: Myths and truths about mediation analysis. Journal of Consumer Research, 37, 197–206.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media New York 2012

Authors and Affiliations

  • John W. Payne
    • 1
  • Namika Sagara
    • 1
  • Suzanne B. Shu
    • 2
  • Kirstin C. Appelt
    • 3
  • Eric J. Johnson
    • 3
  1. 1.Fuqua School of BusinessDuke UniversityDurhamUSA
  2. 2.Anderson School of BusinessUniversity of CaliforniaLos AngelesUSA
  3. 3.School of BusinessColumbia UniversityNew YorkUSA

Personalised recommendations