Skip to main content
Log in

The Year in Review: Economics at the Antitrust Division, 2018–2019

  • Published:
Review of Industrial Organization Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This article highlights the economic analysis that underlay certain enforcement efforts of the Antitrust Division over the past year. The Division’s challenge of AT&T’s acquisition of Time Warner expressly incorporated bargaining theory into the theory of harm; this provided for a rich theoretical framework for evaluating the merger’s impact. The Division also reached a settlement with Atrium Health that prevented the large hospital network from imposing contractual restrictions that undercut health insurers’ efforts to create tiered networks and other plans that promote competition among providers.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In particular, AT&T’s TV offerings consist of its DirecTV satellite business and its DTVNow vMVPD offering, which are available nationwide, and its U-verse product, which is available in areas where it has deployed extensive fiber.

  2. As Netflix’s Chief Content Officer once said: “The goal is to become HBO faster than HBO can become us.” Haas (2013).

  3. Future developments—e.g., additional buildout and 5G—have the potential to increase modestly the average number of Internet choices, although those developments are by-and-large being done by traditional companies such as AT&T and Verizon.

  4. Bargaining models may also predict less harm than price-setting models. For instance, the VGUPPI is one potential tool for estimating the potential magnitude of harm from a vertical merger. Because it assumes that the upstream firm is free to use all of its newfound ability and incentive to increase price, however, in some cases it may predict potential price increases that are more than an order of magnitude larger than those that are predicted by a bargaining model.

  5. In a price-setting model, for instance, the firm that sets the prices need only estimate the willingness to pay of the other side, and in an auction model each bidder is estimating only its own profits and chance of winning, not that of the auction holder.

  6. Because this model does not attempt to capture whatever downstream price changes might happen because of upstream cost changes, the predicted harm is based on only the merged firm’s increased bargaining leverage—not on its desire to see its rivals increase their prices. Of course, the merged firm would directly benefit from its rivals’ charging higher prices, so the model potentially underestimated the negative effects of the merger.

  7. In such a situation a price-discriminating monopolist might also offer fully efficient take-it-or-leave-it contracts.

  8. See p. 13 of the complaint (available at https://www.justice.gov/atr/case-document/file/1012916/download).

  9. A more rigorous mathematical treatment of this can be found in Appendix K of the first report of Professor Carl Shapiro: the Division’s expert at trial. A redacted version of that report is available at https://www.justice.gov/atr/case-document/file/1081336/download.

  10. Ideally one might want to capture feedback effects from linking the two models together, but litigation did not permit the additional work necessary. Gee et al. (2019) addresses this issue.

  11. Atrium Health was known at the time as Carolinas HealthCare System, but changed its name in February 2018, while litigation with the Department of Justice was ongoing. To avoid confusion, in this article we use the Atrium name even when referring to events that took place prior to the name change.

  12. Robinson and Brown (2013), Robinson et al. (2015a, b, c).

  13. Chapter 288 of the 2010 Acts, Massachusetts Laws.

  14. The California Attorney General filed a lawsuit against Sutter Health in March 2018, alleging that Sutter’s contracting practices—including steering restrictions—violate California’s antitrust law.

  15. These figures are based on publicly available inpatient discharge data collected on behalf of the North Carolina Division of Health Service Regulation.

  16. Farrell (2006) makes this point in a different context.

References

  • Atwood, A., & Lo Sasso, A. (2016). The effect of narrow provider networks on health care use. Journal of Health Economics,50, 86–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dafny, L., Hendel, I., Marone, V., & Ody, C. (2017). Narrow networks on the health insurance marketplaces: Prevalence, pricing, and the cost of network breadth. Health Affairs,36(9), 1606–1614.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Emanuel, E., Tanden, N., Altman, S., Armstrong, S., Berwick, D., de Brantes, F., et al. (2012). A systemic approach to containing health care spending. New England Journal of Medicine,367(10), 949–954.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farrell, J. (2006). Efficiency and competition between payment instruments. Review of Network Economics,5(1), 19–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gee, E., Sheu, G., & Taylor, Y. (2019). Effects of vertical integration across upstream and downstream markets: Theory and simulation in the US TV market. Working paper.

  • Gruber, J., & McKnight, R. (2016). Controlling health care costs through limited network insurance plans: Evidence from Massachusetts state employees. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy,8(2), 219–250.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hass, N. (2013, January 29). And the award for the next HBO Goes to… GQ. Retrieved from https://www.gq.com/story/netflix-founder-reed-hastings-house-of-cards-arrested-development.

  • Havighurst, C., & Richman, B. (2010). The provider monopoly problem in health care. Oregon Law Review,89, 847–883.

    Google Scholar 

  • Health Care Cost Institute. (2016). The price-quality paradox in health care. HCCI data brief #3.

  • Hussey, P., Wertheimer, S., & Mehrotra, A. (2013). The association between health care quality and cost: A systematic review. Annals of Internal Medicine,158(1), 27–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mays, G., Claxton, G., & Strunk, B. (2003). Tiered-provider networks: Patients face cost-choice trade-offs. Center for Studying Health System Change, Issue Brief 71.

  • Robinson, J., & Brown, T. (2013). Increases in consumer cost sharing redirect patient volumes and reduce hospital prices for orthopedic surgery. Health Affairs,32(8), 1392–1397.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, J., Brown, T., & Whaley, C. (2015a). Reference-based benefit design changes consumers’ choices and employers’ payments for ambulatory surgery. Health Affairs,34(3), 415–422.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, J., Brown, T., Whaley, C., & Bozic, K. (2015b). Consumer choice between hospital-based and freestanding facilities for arthroscopy. Journal of Bone and Joint Surgery,97(18), 1473–1481.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, J., Brown, T., Whaley, C., & Finlayson, E. (2015c). Association of reference payment for colonoscopy with consumer choices, insurer spending, and procedural complications. JAMA Internal Medicine,175(11), 1783–1789.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sinaiko, A., Landrum, M. B., & Chernew, M. (2017). Enrollment in a health plan with a tiered provider network decreased medical spending by 5 percent. Health Affairs,36(5), 870–875.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sinaiko, A., & Rosenthal, M. (2014). The impact of tiered physician networks on patient choices. Health Services Research,49(4), 1348–1363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jeffrey M. Wilder.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Gee, E., Peters, C. & Wilder, J.M. The Year in Review: Economics at the Antitrust Division, 2018–2019. Rev Ind Organ 55, 537–550 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-019-09726-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-019-09726-1

Keywords

Navigation