Antitrust and Vertical Integration in “New Economy” Industries with Application to Broadband Access

Open Access
Article

Abstract

Whether the firms that supply Internet hardware and software should face restrictions on the use of their property is an important and controversial policy issue. Advocates of “net neutrality”—including President Obama and the current FCC majority—believe that owners of broadband distribution systems (hardware used to distribute Internet and video services) and producers of certain “must-have” video content should be subject to prophylactic regulation that transcends present-day antitrust law enforcement. In the economic terms that are used in debates on competition policy, the concern is with vertical integration that may give firms both the opportunity (through denial of access or price discrimination) and incentive (increased profit) to restrict competition. This paper’s central point is that virtually every production process in the economy is vertically integrated, and economics predicts changes in the extent of vertical integration—that is, changes in the boundaries of the firm—in response to changes in relative prices, technology, or institutions. Both vertical integration and changes in the extent of vertical integration are benign characteristics of efficient, dynamic, competitive markets. While there is no shortage of theoretical models in which vertical integration may be harmful, most such models have restrictive assumptions and ambiguous welfare predictions—even when market power is assumed to be present. Empirical evidence that vertical integration or vertical restraints are harmful is weak, compared to evidence that vertical integration is beneficial—again, even in cases where market power appears to be present. Thus, it is reasonable to conclude that prophylactic regulation is not necessary, and may well reduce welfare. Sound policy is to wait for ex post evidence of harm to justify interventions in specific cases. Net neutrality, recently enacted by the FCC but subject to judicial review, is an unfortunate idea.

Keywords

Access Antitrust Broadband Common carrier Contracting Essential facilities Ex ante regulation Firm boundaries Industrial organization Internet Net neutrality New economy Pin factory Schumpeter Vertical integration Vertical restraints 

JEL Classification

K20 K21 K23 L10 L11 L14 L22 L23 L24 L38 L40 L42 L50 L59 L82 L86 L96 

References

  1. Acemoglu, D., & Cao, D. V. (2010). Innovation by entrants and incumbents. NBER working paper 16411. September.Google Scholar
  2. [Adelphia 2006] See FCC (2006).Google Scholar
  3. Arrow, K. J. (1962). Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In M. G. Harold (Ed.) Chairman, Universities-National Bureau Committee for economic research, 1962. The rate and direction of inventive activity: Economic and social factors, Cambridge MA: NBER books, National Bureau of economic research, Inc.Google Scholar
  4. Baker J. B. (2007) Beyond Schumpeter vs arrow: How antitrust fosters innovation. Antitrust Law Journal 74(3): 575–602Google Scholar
  5. Brown Shoe v. United States. (1962). 370 U.S. 294, 323–334.Google Scholar
  6. Burt D. L., Lemley M. A. (2009) The patent crisis and how the courts can solve it. University Chicago Press, ChicagoGoogle Scholar
  7. Bustos, A. E., & Galetovic, A. (2009). Vertical integration and sabotage with a regulated bottleneck monopoly. The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy Issue 1 Article 35.Google Scholar
  8. Buttrick J. (1952) The inside contract system. The Journal of Economic History 12(3): 205–221Google Scholar
  9. Coase R. (1937) The nature of the firm. Economica 4(16): 386–405CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Cooper J. C., Froeb L. M., O’Brien D., Vita M. G. (2005) Vertical antitrust policy as a problem of inference. International Journal of Industrial Organization 23(7–8): 639–664CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Diamond, P., Vartiainen, H. (eds) (2007) Behavioral economics and its applications. Princeton University Press, PrincetonGoogle Scholar
  12. Dutton H. I., Jones S. R. H. (1983) Invention and innovation in the British pin industry, 1790–1850. Business History Review 62: 175–193CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Eastman Kodak Co. v. (1992). Image technical services Inc., 504 U.S. 451.Google Scholar
  14. Englander E. J. (1987) The inside contract system of production and organization: A neglected aspect of the history of the firm. Labor History 28: 4429–4446CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Evans D. S., Schmalensee R. (2002) Some economic aspects of antitrust analysis in dynamically competitive industries, In Innovation policy and the economy 2. National Bureau of Economic Research Inc, Cambridge, pp 1–50Google Scholar
  16. FCC. (2006). [Adelphia] In the matter of applications for consent to the assignment and/or transfer of control of licenses, MB Docket No. 05-192. Memorandum opinion and order, released July 21, 2006. FCC 06-105.Google Scholar
  17. FCC. (2010). Open internet order. FCC No. 10-201 (rel. Dec. 23, 2010).Google Scholar
  18. Fellner W. (1951) The influence of market structure on technological progress. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 65: 556–577CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Feng, L., & Hendrikse, G. (2010). Cognition and governance structure. Working paper. University of Rotterdam. Presented at workshop on valuation methods in agro-food and environmental economics, Barcelona, July 1, 2010. http://www.creda.es/Web%20workshop%202010/full%20papers/Feng.pdf.
  20. Gibbons R. (2010) Inside organizations: Pricing, politics, and path dependence. Annual Review of Economics 2: 337–365CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Goldfine D. A. J., Vorrasi K. M. (2004) The fall of the Kodak aftermarket doctrine: Dying a slow death in the lower courts. Antitrust Law Journal 72(1): 209–231Google Scholar
  22. Hahn, R., & Passel, P. (2010). Greasy pole economics. regulation2point0 (August 19) http://regulation2point0.org/.
  23. Hart O., Holmstrom B. (2010) A theory of firm scope. Quarterly Journal of Economics 125(2): 483–513CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Hazlett, T. W. (2010). Shooting blanks on wireless policy. Financial times FT.com. October 5.Google Scholar
  25. Holmes O. W. Jr. (1897) The path of the law. Harvard Law Review 10: 457CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Holmstrom B., Roberts J. (1998) The boundaries of the firm revisited. Journal of Economic Perspectives 2: 73–94Google Scholar
  27. Jackson, C. K., & Schneider, H. S. (2010). Do social connections reduce moral hazard? Evidence from the New York City taxi industry. NBER working paper 16279.Google Scholar
  28. Joskow, P. L. (2005). Vertical integration. In Handbook of new institutional economics, Ch. 13 (pp. 319–348). Kluwer handbook of new institutional economics 2005, Section 4.Google Scholar
  29. Kahn A. E. (1988) The economics of regulation: Principles and institutions. MIT Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  30. Klein B., Crawford R. G., Alchian A. A. (1978) Vertical integration, appropriable rents, and the competitive contracting process. Journal of Law and Economics 21(2): 297–326CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Kodak. (1992). See Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services Inc.Google Scholar
  32. Lafontaine F., Slade M. (2007) Vertical integration and firm boundaries: The evidence. Journal of Economic Literature XLV: 629–685CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Lafontaine, F., & Slade, M. (2008a). Inter-Firm contracts: Evidence. Forthcoming in Gibbons & Roberts (eds) Working Paper. Handbook of organizational economics, Princeton University Press 2012.Google Scholar
  34. Lafontaine F., Slade M. E. (2008b) Exclusive contracts and vertical restraints: Empirical evidence and public policy. In: Paolo B. (eds) Handbook of antitrust economics. MIT Press, Cambridge, pp 391–414Google Scholar
  35. Lee J. S. (2010a) The functions and fortunes of English small towns at the close of the middle ages: Evidence from John Leland’s itinerary. Urban History 37: 1–25CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Lee, R. S. (2010b). Vertical integration and exclusivity in platform and two-sided markets. Working paper. Stern School of Business, New York University. http://pages.stern.nyu.edu/~rslee/papers/VIExclusivity.pdf.
  37. Lemley, M. A. (2010). Industry-specific antitrust policy for innovation. Working paper. Stanford Law School. http://ssrn.com/abstract=1670197
  38. Lyons B. R. (1996) Empirical relevance of efficient contract theory: Inter-firm contracts. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 12(4): 27–52CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Microsoft. (2002). See United States v. Microsoft Corp.Google Scholar
  40. Nocera, J. (2010). The struggle for what we already have. New York Times. September 3. http://www.nytimes.com/2010/09/04/business/04nocera.html?_r=1&pagewanted=print.
  41. Noll, R. G., & Owen, B. M. (1994). United States v. AT&T: The Economic Issues. In J. Kwoka & L. White (Eds.) The antitrust revolution 2nd edn. Scott Foresman 1988.Google Scholar
  42. Ordover J. A., Saloner G., Salop S. (1990) Equilibrium vertical foreclosure. American Economic Review 80: 127–142Google Scholar
  43. Organization for economic co-operation and development (OECD). (1993). Technology diffusion: Tracing the flows of embodied R&D in eight OECD countries. DSTI/EAS (93):5 Rev.1. Paris.Google Scholar
  44. Owen, B. M. (2007). Antecedents to net neutrality. Regulation Fall 14.Google Scholar
  45. Posner R. A. (2000) Antitrust in the new economy. Antitrust Law Journal 68: 925–943Google Scholar
  46. Pratten C. F. (1980) The manufacture of pins. Journal of Economic Literature XVIII: 93–96Google Scholar
  47. Rhodes-Kropf M., Robinson D. T. (2008) The market for mergers and the boundaries of the firm. Journal of Finance 63(3): 1169–1211CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Riordan M., Salop S. (1995) Evaluating vertical mergers: A post-Chicago approach. Antitrust Law Journal 63: 513–568Google Scholar
  49. Riordan M. H. (2008) Competitive effects of vertical integration. In: Paolo B. (eds) Handbook of antitrust economics. MIT Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  50. Robinson D. T. (2008) Strategic alliances and the boundaries of the firm. The Review of Financial Studies 21(2): 649–681CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Salinger M. A. (1988) Vertical mergers and market foreclosure. Quarterly Journal of Economics 103: 345–356CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Salop S. C., Scheffman D. T. (1987) Cost-raising strategies. Journal of Industrial Economics 36(1): 19–34CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  53. Schmalensee R. (1992) Sunk cost and market structure: A review article. Journal of Industrial Economics 40: 125–134CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Schmalensee, R. (2000). Antitrust issues in Schumpeterian industries. The American Economic Review. 90(2):192–196. In Papers and proceedings of the 112th annual meeting of the American Economic Association (May, 2000).Google Scholar
  55. Schmalensee, R., Willig, R. D. (eds) (1989) The handbook of industrial organization. Elsevier , North HollandGoogle Scholar
  56. Schuett, F. (2010). Network neutrality: A survey of the economic literature. Review of Network Economics. 9(2):1 http://www.bepress.com/rne/vol9/iss2/1.
  57. Schumpeter J. (1950) Capitalism, socialism and democracy (3rd ed.). Harper, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  58. Smith, A. (1776). An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations, 2 Vols., Everyman’s library. London: Dent & Sons 1904.Google Scholar
  59. Stewart P. (1966) Dissent in United States v. Von’s Grocery. 384 U.S. 270: 281Google Scholar
  60. Stigler G. J. (1951) The division of labor is limited by the extent of the market. Journal of Political Economy 59: 185–193CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  61. Sutton J. (1991) Sunk costs and market structure. MIT Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  62. Swan P. (1970) Market structure and technological progress: The influence of monopoly on product innovation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 84: 627–638CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  63. Teece D. J. (1992) Competition, cooperation, and innovation: Organizational arrangements for regimes of rapid technological progress. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 18: 1–25CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  64. Trinko. (2004). see Verizon Communications Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko.Google Scholar
  65. United States Antitrust Modernization Commission. (2007). Report and Recommendations. http://govinfo.library.unt.edu/amc/report_recommendation/amc_final_report.pdf.
  66. U.S. Department of Justice—Federal Trade Commission Horizontal Merger Guidelines (rev. 2010) http://www.ftc.gov/os/2010/08/100819hmg.pdf
  67. United States v. Microsoft Corp. (2002). 253 F.3d 34 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (en banc); Final Judgment No. 98-1232, 2002 WL 31654530 (D.D.C. Nov. 12, 2002)).Google Scholar
  68. United States v. Von’s Grocery. (1966). 384 U. S. 270, 281.Google Scholar
  69. Varian, H. R. (2001). High technology industries and market structure. Working paper, University of California at Berkeley. http://people.ischool.berkeley.edu/~hal/Papers/structure
  70. Verizon Communications Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, 540 U. S. 398 (2004). [Trinko 2004].Google Scholar
  71. Williamson O. E. (1975) Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust implications. Free Press, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  72. Williamson O. E. (1985) The economic institutions of capitalism. Free Press, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  73. Williamson O. E. (1991) Comparative economic organization: The analysis of discrete structural alternatives. Administrative Science Quarterly 36(2): 269–296CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  74. Williamson O. E. (1996) The mechanisms of governance. Oxford University Press, Oxford, UKGoogle Scholar
  75. Yoo C. S. (2002) Vertical integration and media regulation in the new economy. Yale Journal on Regulation 19: 171Google Scholar
  76. Zanarone G. (2009) Vertical Restraints and the Law: Evidence from automobile franchising. Journal of Law and Economics 52: 691CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© The Author(s) 2011

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Stanford UniversityStanfordUSA
  2. 2.Stanford Institute for Economic Policy ResearchStanfordUSA

Personalised recommendations