Review of Economics of the Household

, Volume 4, Issue 4, pp 299–323 | Cite as

Gender ideology, division of housework, and the geographic mobility of families

Household Decision Making in Germany and South Africa

Abstract

The paper studies the relevance of gender ideology for the geographic mobility of families using data from the German Socio-economic Panel. The analysis proceeds in two steps. First, it is shown that single men and women—who are in some sense “unconstrained” optimizers—reveal identical mobility patterns. There are no fundamental gender differences in the inter-regional mobility of German singles. Second, I focus on dual-earner households and split this group into “traditional” and “egalitarian” couples using information on their factual division of housework rather than their reported gender ideology. Separate migration analyses for both groups reveal important differences indicating the significance of gender ideology in families’ migration behavior: job-related characteristics of men statistically dominate those of women in traditional couples, whereas in egalitarian couples, male and female characteristics have the same effect on family migration behavior, i.e. there is no gender bias. Failure to account for the heterogeneity in gendered family roles across families thus misses an important explanatory factor in migration research.

Keywords

Household decision making Migration Division of housework Gender ideology 

JEL Classifications

D13 J16 J61 

References

  1. Baltagi, B. H. (1995). Econometric analysis of panel data. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
  2. Beblo, M. (1999). How do German couples spend their time? A panel data analysis. DIW-Vierteljahrshefte zur Wirtschaftsforschung, 68, 146–152.Google Scholar
  3. Berger, M., Foster, M., & Wallston, B. S. (1978). Finding Two Jobs. In: R. Rapoport, & R. N. Rapoport (Eds.), Working couples. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
  4. Bielby, W. T., & Bielby, D. D. (1992). I will follow him: family ties, gender-role beliefs, and reluctance to relocate for a better job. American Journal of Sociology, 97, 1241–1267.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Bird, G. A., & Bird, G. W. (1985). Determinants of mobility in two-earner families: Does the wife’s income count? Journal of Marriage and the Family, 47, 753–758.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Blossfeld, H.-P., & Timm, A. (2003). Who marries whom? Educational systems as marriage markets in modern societies (European Studies of Population, Vol 12). Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.Google Scholar
  7. Bover, O., & Arellano, M. (2002). Learning About Migration Decisions from the Migrants: Using Complementary Datasets to Model Intra-regional Migrations in Spain. Journal of Population Economics, 15, 357–380.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Boyle, P., Cooke, T. J., Halfacree, K., & Smith, D. (2001). A cross-national comparison of the impact of family migration on women’s employment status. Demography, 38, 201–213.Google Scholar
  9. Büchel, F. (2000). Tied movers, tied stayers: The higher risk of overqualification among married women in West Germany. In: S. S. Gustafsson, & D. E. Meulders (Eds.),Gender and the labour market. Econometric evidence of obstacles to achieving gender equality, New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  10. Compton, J., & Pollak, R. A. (2004). Why are power couples increasingly concentrated in large metropolitan areas? NBER Working Paper 10918.Google Scholar
  11. Costa, D. L., & Kahn, M. E. (2000). Power couples: Changes in the location choice of the college educated, 1940–1990. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115, 1287–1315.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. DaVanzo, J. (1976). Why families move: A model of the geographic mobility of married couples. Santa Monica: RAND.Google Scholar
  13. DaVanzo, Julie (1981). Microeconomic approaches to studying migration decisions. In: G. F. De Jong, & R. W. Gardner (Eds.), Migration decision making, New York: Pergamon Press.Google Scholar
  14. De Laat, Joost and Almudena. Sevilla-Sanz (2004). Working women, husband’s home time, and lowest-low fertility in Europe. Paper presented at the 18th Annual Conference of the European Society for Population Economics, Bergen.Google Scholar
  15. Duncan, R. P., & Perucci, C. (1976). Dual occupation families and migration. American Sociological Review, 41, 252–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Fischer, C. S. (1982). To dwell among friends. Chicago: Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
  17. Granovetter, M. S. (1974). Getting a job. A study of contacts and careers. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  18. Greenstein, T. (1996). Husbands’ participation in domestic labour: Interactive effects of wives’ and husbands’ gender ideologies. Journal of Marriage and the Family, 58, 585–595.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Greenstein, T. (2000). Economic dependence, gender, and the division of labor in the home: A replication and extension. Journal of Marriage and the Family, 62, 322–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Greenwood, M. J. (1975). Research on internal migration in the United States: A survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 13, 397–433.Google Scholar
  21. Greenwood, M. J. (1997). Internal migration in developed countries. In: M. R. Rosenzweig, & O. Stark (Eds.), Handbook of population and family economics, Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
  22. Hersch, J., & Stratton, L. S. (1994). Housework, wages, and the division of housework time for employed spouses. American Economic Review, 84(Papers and Proceedings), 120–125.Google Scholar
  23. Hiller, D. V. (1984). Power dependence and the division of family work. Sex Roles, 10, 1003–1019.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Hosmer, D. W., & Lemeshow, S. (2000). Applied logistic regression. 2nd ed. New York, Wiley.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Huber, J., & Spitze, G. (1983). Sex stratification: Children, housework, and jobs. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
  26. Hunt, J. (2000). Why do people still live in East Germany? NBER Working Paper 7564.Google Scholar
  27. Hunt, J. (2004). Are migrants more skilled than non-migrants? Repeat, return and same employer migrants. DIW Discussion Paper 422.Google Scholar
  28. Inglehart, R., & Norris, P. (2003). Rising tide: Gender equality and cultural change around the world. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  29. Jürges, H. (1998a). Beruflich bedingte Umzüge von Doppelverdienern [Job-related Geographic Mobility of Dual-Earner Couples]. Zeitschrift für Soziologie, 27, 358–377.Google Scholar
  30. Jürges, H. (1998b). Einkommen und berufliche Situation von Doppelverdienern nach Umzügen [Income and Job Characteristics of Dual Earners After Migration]. Mitteilungen aus der Arbeitsmarkt- und Berufsforschung, 31, 234–243.Google Scholar
  31. Lansing, J. B., & Mueller, E. (1967). The geographic mobility of labor. Ann Arbor: Institute for Social Research, University of Michigan.Google Scholar
  32. Lennon, M. C., & Rosenfeld, S. (1994). Relative fairness and the division of housework: The importance of options. American Journal of Sociology, 100, 506–531.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Lichter, D. T. (1982). The migration of dual-worker families: Does the wife’s job matter? Social Science Quarterly, 63, 49–57.Google Scholar
  34. Lichter, D. T. (1983). Socioeconomic returns to migration among married women. Social Forces, 62, 487–503.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Long, L. H. (1974). Women’s labour force participation and the residential mobility of families. Social Forces, 52, 342–348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Lundberg, S., & Pollak, R. A. (1996). Bargaining and distribution in marriage. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10, 139–158.Google Scholar
  37. Lundberg, S., & Pollak, R. A. (2003). Efficiency in marriage. Review of Economics of the Household, 1, 153–167.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Manser, M., & Brown, M. (1980). Marriage and household decision making. A bargaining analysis. International Economic Review, 21, 31–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Maxwell, N. L. (1988). Economic returns to migration: Marital status and gender differences. Social Science Quarterly, 60, 108–121.Google Scholar
  40. McElroy, M. B., & Horney, M. (1981). Nash bargained household decisions. International Economic Review, 22, 333–349.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Mincer, J. (1978). Family migration decisions. Journal of Political Economy, 86, 749–773.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Morrison, D. R., & Lichter, D. T. (1988). Family migration and female employment: The problem of underemployment among married women. Journal of Marriage and Family, 50, 161–172.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Nivalainen, S. (2004). Determinants of family migration: Short moves vs. Long Moves. Journal of Population Economics, 17, 157–175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Ott, N. (1992). Intrafamily bargaining and household decisions. Berlin: Springer.Google Scholar
  45. Rossi, P. H. (1980). Why families move. 2nd ed. Beverly Hills: Sage.Google Scholar
  46. Sandell, S. H. (1977). Women and the economics of family migration. Review of Economics and Statistics, 59, 406–414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Shihadeh, E. S. (1991). The prevalence of husband-centered migration: Employment consequences for married mothers. Journal of Marriage and the Family, 53, 432–444.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Sjaastad, L. A. (1962). The costs and returns of human migration. Journal of Political Economy, 70, 80–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. SOEP Group (2001). The German socio-economic panel (SOEP) after more than 15 years – Overview. Vierteljahrshefte zur Wirtschaftsforschung, 70, 7–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. Spitze, G. (1984). The effect of family migration on wives’ employment: How long does it last? Social Science Quarterly, 65, 21–36.Google Scholar
  51. United Nations (2005). Human development report 2005. New York: United Nations Development Programme.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2006

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Mannheim Research Institute for the Economics of AgingUniversity of MannheimMannheimGermany

Personalised recommendations