Journal of Regulatory Economics

, Volume 31, Issue 1, pp 83–107 | Cite as

Can consumers enforce environmental regulations? The role of the market in hazardous waste compliance

Original Article

Abstract

We examine the U.S. hazardous waste management industry to assess the role that consumers play in encouraging environmental compliance. We first examine whether environmental performance affects consumer demand and find that noncompliance does decrease demand, at least in the short term. Next we consider whether market characteristics affect compliance behavior. While we do not find evidence that market size affects behavior, local competition does appear to increase compliance. However, as competition becomes less localized, it has a smaller effect. Finally, regardless of the pressures exerted by consumers to comply, commercial managers are less likely to be in compliance than on-site managers.

Keywords

Commercial environmentalism Compliance Enforcement Hazardous waste Market size Competition 

JEL Classifications

Q28 K42 D21 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Afsah S., Laplante B., Wheeler D. (1997). Regulation in the information age: Indonesian public information program for environmental management. Washington D.C., World Bank Development Research GroupGoogle Scholar
  2. Alberini A., Bartholomew J. (1999). The determinants of hazardous waste disposal choice: An empirical analysis of halogenated solvent waste shipments. Contemporary Economic Policy, 7, 309–320CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Anton W.R.Q., Deltas G., Khanna M. (2004). Incentives for environmental self-regulation and implications for environmental performance. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 48, 632–654CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Arora S., Cason T. (1996). Why do firms volunteer to exceed environmental regulations? Understanding participation in EPA’s 33/50 Program. Land Economics, 72, 413–432CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Badrinath S.G., Bolster P.J. (1996). The role of market forces in EPA enforcement activity. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 10, 165–181CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Beard T.R. (1990). Bankruptcy and care choice. RAND Journal of Economics, 21, 626–634CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Bjrner T.B., Hansen L.G., Russell C.S. (2004). Environmental labeling and consumers’ choice—An empirical analysis of the effect of the nordic swan. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 47, 411–434CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Cohen, M. A. (1999). Monitoring and enforcement of environmental policy. International Yearbook of Environmental and Resource Economics, 1999/2000. In: T. Tietenberg & H. Folmer (Eds) Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar PublishingGoogle Scholar
  9. Earnhart D. (2004). The effects of community characteristics on polluter compliance levels. Land Economics, 80, 408–432CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Environmental Council of the States. (ECOS). (2005). State commissioners urge congress to restore EPA funding to states. April 12, 2005 Press Release.Google Scholar
  11. Environmental Law Institute. (ELI). (1998). An analysis of state superfund programs: 50-state study, 1998 Update.Google Scholar
  12. Foulon J., Lanoie P., Laplante B. (2002). Incentives for pollution control: Regulation or information?. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 44, 169–187CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Grabosky P.N. (1994). Green markets: Environmental regulation by the private sector. Law and Policy, 16, 419–448CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Greene, W. H. (1992). A statistical model for credit scoring. Working Paper No. EC-92-29, New York University Department of Economics, Stern School of Business.Google Scholar
  15. Hamilton J.T. (1995). Pollution as news: Media and stock market reactions to the toxics release inventory data. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 28, 98–113CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Konar S., Cohen M.A. (1997). Information as regulation: The effect of community right to know laws on toxic emissions. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 32, 109–124CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Lanoie P., Laplante B., Roy M. (1998). Can capital markets create incentives for pollution control?. Ecological Economics, 26, 31–41CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Peretz J.H., Bohm R.A., Jasienczyk P.D. (1997). Environmental policy and the reduction of waste. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 16, 556–574CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Poirier D.J. (1980). Partial observability in bivariate probit models. Journal of Econometrics, 12, 209–217CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Sigman H. (1996). The effects of hazardous waste taxes on waste generation and disposal. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 30, 199–217CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Teisl M.F., Roe B., Hicks R.L. (2002). Can eco-labels tune a market? Evidence from dolphin-safe labeling. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 43, 339–359CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. (EPA). (2003). FY 2002 enforcement and compliance assurance report: Environmental results through Smart enforcement. Report Number EPA300-R-03-002.Google Scholar
  23. U. S. General Accounting Office. (GAO). (2002). Information on the environmental protection agency’s actual and proposed funding for enforcement activities for fiscal years 2001 through 2003. Report Number GAO-02-1096R.Google Scholar
  24. World Bank. (2000). Greening industry: New roles for communities, markets, and governments. Washington, D.C. World Bank and Oxford University Press.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2006

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.College of William and MaryWilliamsburgUSA

Personalised recommendations