Skip to main content
Log in

Does the invisible hand hold or lead? Market adjustment in an entrepreneurial economy

  • Published:
The Review of Austrian Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Adam Smith's “invisible hand” is one of the best-known phrases in economics, but its meaning is somewhat ambiguous. The invisible hand might be viewed as holding the economy close to equilibrium, yet Smith actually says that individuals are led by an invisible hand. Entrepreneurial forces lead an economy along a path that generates economic progress, and that path is determined by the disruptive forces of entrepreneurship. Rather than viewing an economy as tending toward an equilibrium, it is more accurate to view an economy as characterized by continuing progress, led by the invisible hand of entrepreneurial activity.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Alchian, A. A., and H. Demsetz (1972). “Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization.” American Economic Review 62: 777–795.

  • Arrow, K. J., and G. Debreu (1954). “The Existence of an Equilibrium for a Competitive Economy.” Econometrica 22: 265–290.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arthur, W. B. (1989). “Competing Technologies, Increasing Returns, and Lock-In by Historical Events.” Economic Journal 99: 116–131.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W. J. (2002). “The Free Market Innovation Machine: Analyzing the Growth Miracle of Capitalism.” Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boudreaux, D. J. and R. G. Holcombe (1989). “The Coasian and Knightian Theories of the Firm.” Managerial and Decision Economics 10: 147–154.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chamberlin, E. (1933). “The Theory of Monopolistic Competition.” Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galbraith, J. K. (1958). “The Affluent Society.” Boston: Houghton Mifflin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garrison, R. W. (2001). “Time and Money: The Macroeconomics of Capital Structure.” London and New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1945). “The Use of Knowledge in Society,” American Economic Review 35: 519–530.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. R. (1939). “Value and Capital: An Inquiry Into Some Fundamental Principles of Economic Theory.” Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G. (1989). “Economic Models and Methodology.” New York: Greenwood.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G. (1998). “Entrepreneurship and Economic Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 1: 45–62.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G. (1999). “Equilibrium Versus the Invisible Hand.” Review of Austrian Economics 12: 227–243.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G. (2003a). “Progress and Entrepreneurship.” Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 6: 3–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G. (2003b). “The Origins of Entrepreneurial Opportunities.” Review of Austrian Economics 16: 25–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J. M. (1936). “The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money.” New York: Harcourt, Brace & Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner, I. M. (1973). “Competition and Entrepreneurship.” Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kohn, M. (2004). “Value and Exchange.” Cato Journal 24: 303–339.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, A. (1890). “Principles of Economics.” London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, J. (1933). “The Economics of Imperfect Competition.” London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1947). “Foundations of Economic Analysis.” Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1934). “The Theory of Economic Development.” Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1939). “Business Cycles: A Theoretical, Historical, and Statistical Analysis of the Capitalist Process.” New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1942). “Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy.” New York: Harper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shaffer, G. (2005). “Slotting Allowances and Optimal Product Variety” Advances in Economic Analysis and Policy 5: www.bepress.com/bejeap/advances/vol5/iss1/art3/

  • Smith, A. [1776] (1937). “An Inquiry Into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations.” New York: Modern Library.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R. M. (1956). “A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 70: 65–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Randall G. Holcombe.

Additional information

JEL Code B53, D21, E32, O31

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Holcombe, R.G. Does the invisible hand hold or lead? Market adjustment in an entrepreneurial economy. Rev Austrian Econ 19, 189–201 (2006). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-006-7347-2

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-006-7347-2

Keywords

Navigation