Why do military dictatorships become presidential democracies? Mapping the democratic interests of autocratic regimes
- 48 Downloads
Abstract
Recent data show that virtually all military dictatorships that democratize become presidential democracies. I hypothesize that the reason is that military interests are able to coordinate on status-preserving institutional change prior to democratization and prefer political institutions with strong veto players. Civilian interests are more likely to suffer from coordination failure by being more diverse and less cohesive, implying that most military democratizations are planned partially while most democratization events from civilian autocracy are unforeseen or poorly planned. Exploring the characteristics of 111 democratization episodes between 1950 and 2017 illustrates features broadly consistent with further theoretical predictions.
Keywords
Dictatorship Democracy Political institutionsJEL Classifications
P16 D72 D74 K16Notes
Acknowledgements
I thank Marina Rapp for providing the impetus and some of the first ideas for this paper, and Sascha Becker, Geoffrey Brennan, Michael Dorsch, Stephan Gohmann, Arye Hillman, Jean Lacroix, Martin Rode, Ahmed Skali, participants of the first conference on the Political Economy of Democracy and Dictatorship in Münster (February 2017) and the 10th Australasian Public Choice Conference in Melbourne (December 2017), three anonymous reviewers and the editor (Bill Shughart) for comments on earlier versions. I am also grateful to the Jan Wallander and Tom Hedelius Foundation for generous financial support. Needless to say, all remaining errors are entirely my fault.
Supplementary material
References
- Acemoglu, D., & Johnson, S. (2006). Economic backwardness in political perspective. American Political Science Review, 100(1), 115–131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Acemoglu, D., Naidu, S., Restrepo, P., & Robinson, J. A. (2019). Democracy does cause growth. Journal of Political Economy, 127(1), 47–100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Bell, C. (2016). Coup d’état and democracy. Comparative Political Studies, 49(9), 1167–1200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Bidner, C., & Francois, P. (2013). The emergence of political accountability. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128(3), 1397–1448.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Bjørnskov, C., & Pfaff, K. (2017). The effect of coups d’état on physical integrity rights. Working paper, Aarhus University.Google Scholar
- Bjørnskov, C., & Rode, M. (in press). Regimes and regime transitions: A new dataset on democracy, coups, and political institutions. Forthcoming in Review of International Organizations.Google Scholar
- Bjørnskov, C., & Voigt, S. (2018). Why do governments call a state of emergency? On the determinants of using emergency constitutions. European Journal of Political Economy, 54, 110–123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Blanchard, O. J., & Fischer, S. (1989). Lectures on macroeconomics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
- Boix, C., Miller, M., & Rosatto, S. (2013). A complete dataset of political regimes, 1800–2007. Comparative Political Studies, 46(12), 1523–1554.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent: Logical foundations of constitutional democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Bueno de Mesquita, B., Smith, A., Siverson, R. M., & Morrow, J. D. (2003). The logic of political survival. Cambridge: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Cheibub, J. A., Gandhi, J., & Vreeland, J. R. (2010). Democracy and dictatorship revisited. Public Choice, 143(1–2), 67–101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Congleton, R. D. (2010). Perfecting parliament. Constitutional reform, liberalism, and the rise of Western democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Debs, A. (2016). Living by the sword and dying by the sword? Leadership transitions in and out of dictatorships. International Studies Quarterly, 60, 73–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Elkins, Z., Ginsburg, T., & Melton, J. (2009). The endurance of national constitutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Geddes, B. (1999). What do we know about democratization after twenty years? Annual Review of Political Science, 2, 115–144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1994). Protection for sale. American Economic Review, 84(4), 833–850.Google Scholar
- Henisz, W. (2017). Political constrains index (PolCon) dataset. University of Pennsylvania; dataset and codebook. Retrieved January 2017, from https://whartonmgmt.wufoo.com/forms/political-constraint-index-polcon-dataset/.
- Hillman, A. L. (1982). Declining industries and political-support protectionist motives. American Economic Review, 72(5), 1180–1187.Google Scholar
- Ishak, P. W. (2019). Autocratic survival strategies: Does oil make a difference? Peace Economics, Peace Science and Public Policy, 25(2), 1–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Kokkonen, A., & Sundell, A. (in press). Leader succession and civil war. Forthcoming in Comparative Political Studies.Google Scholar
- Kurrild-Klitgaard, P. (2000). The constitutional economics of autocratic succession. Public Choice, 103(1–2), 63–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Lipset, S. M. (1959). Social requisites of democracy: Economic development and political legitimacy. American Political Science Review, 53(1), 69–105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- North, D. (1991). Institutions. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(1), 97–112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- North, D., & Weingast, B. (1989). Constitutions and commitment: The evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. Journal of Economic History, 49(4), 803–832.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action: Public goods and the theory of groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
- Olson, M. (1982). The rise and decline of nations: Economic growth, stagflation, and social rigidities. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
- PARLINE. (2019). Database on national parliaments. Retrieved May 2019, from http://www.ipu.org/parline-e/parlinesearch.asp.
- Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (1999). The size and scope of government: Comparative politics with rational politicians. European Economic Review, 43(4–6), 699–735.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2006). Democracy and development: The devil is in the details. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 96(5), 319–324.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Przeworski, A. (1991). Democracy and the market: Political and economic reforms in Eastern Europe and Latin America. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Treisman, D. (2017). Democracy by mistake. NBER Working Paper No. w23944.Google Scholar
- Tullock, G. (1967). The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies, and theft. Western Economic Journal, 5(3), 224–232.Google Scholar
- Tullock, G. (1987). Autocracy. Dordrecht: Klüwer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Tullock, G. (2001). Monarchies, hereditary and non-hereditary. In W. F. Shugart & L. Razzolini (Eds.), The Elgar companion to public choice (pp. 140–156). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
- Wintrobe, R. (1990). The tinpot and the totalitarian: An economic theory of dictatorship. American Political Science Review, 84(3), 849–872.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Yu, S., & Jong-A-Pin, J. (2016). Political leader survival: Does competence matter? Public Choice, 166(1–2), 113–142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar