Titles for me but not for thee: transitional gains trap of property rights extension in Colombia
Abstract
I apply Tullock’s transitional gains trap to the formalization of property titles in Latin America to understand public choice problems in mending institutions. In an area where land is owned by formal and informal institutions, policies to extend property rights will not be supported by voters holding legal title because it will devalue their property. To test this I use data from Colombia where a peace deal to end a 50-year conflict with Revolutionary Armed Forces of Colombia rebels was reached in 2016 and put to a public referendum. The deal included formalization of property titles across the nation as well as an end to the conflict. Using municipal-level data on voting and property ownership and controlling for conflict history, I find potential losses to formal property holders pushed median voter preferences toward dissension. A 1% increase in legally titled land increases dissenting vote share by 3% points. These results are relevant to institutional reforms anywhere with corrupted property rights.
Keywords
Referendum Property rights Violence Transitional gains trapJEL Classification
D72 D74Notes
Acknowledgements
The author would like to thank Josh Hall, Bryan McCannon, Lynne Kiesling, Bonnie Wilson, Michael Munger, two anonymous referees, and many helpful insights from commenters at Public Choice Society, Southern Economic Association, and American Institute of Economic Research meetings and the Universidad de Los Andes CEDE for data assistance.
References
- Acemoglu, D. (2006). A simple model of inefficient institutions. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 108(4), 515–546.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Acemoglu, D., & Johnson, S. (2005). Unbundling institutions. Journal of Political Economy, 113(5), 949–995.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Acevedo, K., & Bornacelly, I. (2016). Panel municipal del CEDE. Centro de Estudios sobre Desarrollo Económico.Google Scholar
- Albertus, M., & Kaplan, O. (2013). Land reform as a counterinsurgency policy. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 57(2), 198–231.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Alpert, M. (2016). Politics roils Colombia’s tentative peace deal with the FARC. https://foreignpolicy.com/2016/07/18/politics-roils-colombias-tentative-peace-deal-with-the-farc-eln-santos-uribe/.
- Alston, L. J., Libecap, G. D., & Mueller, B. (1999). A model of rural conflict: Violence and land reform policy in Brazil. Environment and Development Economics, 4(2), 135–160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Alston, L. J., Libecap, G. D., & Mueller, B. (2000). Land reform policies, the sources of violent conflict, and implications for deforestation in the Brazilian Amazon. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 39(2), 162–188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Benson, B. L. (1988). Legal evolution in primitive societies. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 144, 772–788.Google Scholar
- Benson, B. L., & Siddiqui, Z. R. (2014). Pashtunwali-law for the lawless, defense for the stateless. International Review of Law and Economics, 37, 108–120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Besley, T. (1995). Property rights and investment incentives: Theory and evidence from Ghana. Journal of Political Economy, 103(5), 903–937.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Brasselle, A.-S., Gaspart, F., & Platteau, J.-P. (2002). Land tenure security and investment incentives: Puzzling evidence from Burkina Faso. Journal of Development Economics, 67(2), 373–418.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Brittain, J. J. (2010). Revolutionary social change in Colombia: The origin and direction of the FARC-EP. London: Pluto Press.Google Scholar
- Brunner, E., Sonstelie, J., & Thayer, M. (2001). Capitalization and the voucher: An analysis of precinct returns from California’s Proposition 174. Journal of Urban Economics, 50(3), 517–536.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Chen, C. (2017). Untitled land, occupational choice, and agricultural productivity. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 9(4), 91–121.Google Scholar
- Colombian State Department. (2016). Election results.Google Scholar
- De Janvry, A., Emerick, K., Gonzalez-Navarro, M., & Sadoulet, E. (2015). Delinking land rights from land use: Certification and migration in Mexico. The American Economic Review, 105(10), 3125–3149.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- De Soto, H. (1989). The other path: The economic answer to terrorism. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
- De Soto, H. (2000). The mystery of capital: Why capitalism triumphs in the West and fails everywhere else. New York: Basic Civitas Books.Google Scholar
- Dehring, C. A., Depken, C. A., & Ward, M. R. (2008). A direct test of the homevoter hypothesis. Journal of Urban Economics, 64(1), 155–170.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Di Tella, R., Galiant, S., & Schargrodsky, E. (2007). The formation of beliefs: Evidence from the allocation of land titles to squatters. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(1), 209–241.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Fajardo, D. (2002). La tierra y el poder político; la reforma agraria y la reforma rural en Colombia. Revista Reforma Agraria Colonización y Cooperativas, 1, 4–20.Google Scholar
- Field, E. (2007). Entitled to work: Urban property rights and labor supply in Peru. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(4), 1561–1602.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Fischel, W. A. (2001). The homevoter hypothesis: How home values influence local government taxation, school finance, and land-use policies. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
- Galiani, S., & Schargrodsky, E. (2010). Property rights for the poor: Effects of land titling. Journal of Public Economics, 94(9), 700–729.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Glaeser, E., Scheinkman, J., & Shleifer, A. (2003). The injustice of inequality. Journal of Monetary Economics, 50(1), 199–222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Goldstein, M., & Udry, C. (2008). The profits of power: Land rights and agricultural investment in Ghana. Journal of Political Economy, 116(6), 981–1022.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Grusczynski, D. M., & Jaramillo, C. F. (2002). Integrating land issues into the broader development agenda. Bogotá: Case Study.Google Scholar
- Ibanez, A. M. (2009). Forced displacement in Colombia: Magnitude and causes. The Economics of Peace and Security Journal, 4(1), 48–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Janvry, A. D., Gonzalez-Navarro, M., & Sadoulet, E. (2014). Are land reforms granting complete property rights politically risky? Electoral outcomes of Mexico’s certification program. Journal of Development Economics, 110, 216–225.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Kerekes, C. B., & Williamson, C. R. (2010). Propertyless in Peru, even with a government land title. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 69(3), 1011–1033.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Leech, G. M. (2011). The FARC: The longest insurgency. Rebels: Fernwood.Google Scholar
- Leeson, P. T. (2007). Trading with bandits. The Journal of Law and Economics, 50(2), 303–321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Leeson, P. T. (2009). The laws of lawlessness. The Journal of Legal Studies, 38(2), 471–503.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Leeson, P. T. (2012). God Damn: The law and economics of monastic malediction. The Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 30(1), 193–216.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Leeson, P. T. (2013). Gypsy law. Public Choice, 155(3–4), 273–292.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Leeson, P. T., & Harris, C. (2018). Wealth-destroying private property rights. World Development, 107, 1–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Levy-Carciente, S. (2017). International property rights index. Property Rights Alliance.Google Scholar
- Murtazashvili, I., & Murtazashvili, J. (2015). Anarchy, self-governance, and legal titling. Public Choice, 162(3), 287–305.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Olson, M. (2008). The rise and decline of nations: Economic growth, stagflation, and social rigidities. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
- Otis, J. (2014). The FARC and Colombia’s illegal drug trade. Woodrow Wilson Center: Encyclopedia of U.S.-Latin American Relations.Google Scholar
- Palacios, P. (2012). Forced displacement: Legal versus illegal crops. Defence and Peace Economics, 23(2), 133–160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Registro Único de Víctimas. (2016). Colombian register of victims report.Google Scholar
- Richani, N. (2013). Systems of violence: The political economy of war and peace in Colombia. New York: Suny Press.Google Scholar
- Robinson, J. A. (2016). La miseria en Colombia. Revista Desarrollo y Sociedad, 76, 9–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Santos Calderón, J. M., & Jiménez, T. (2016). Acuerdo Final Para la Terminación del Conflicti y la Construcción de una Paz Estable y Duradera. Oficina del Alto Comisionado para la Paz.Google Scholar
- Skaperdas, S. (1992). Cooperation, conflict, and power in the absence of property rights. The American Economic Review, 82(4), 720–739.Google Scholar
- Sonin, K. (2003). Why the rich may favor poor protection of property rights. Journal of Comparative Economics, 31(4), 715–731.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Stringham, E. (2015). Private governance: Creating order in economic and social life. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Tullock, G. (1975). The transitional gains trap. The Bell Journal of Economics, 6, 671–678.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Williamson, C. R., & Mathers, R. L. (2011). Economic freedom, culture, and growth. Public Choice, 148(3), 313–335.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- World Values Survey Association. (2010–2014). World value survey wave 6. World Value Survey.Google Scholar