Advertisement

State capacity and public choice: a critical survey

  • Ennio E. Piano
Literature Survey

Abstract

‘State capacity’ is a term associated with a popular argument in fiscal sociology, history, and political economy regarding the role of the state in the process of economic development. Much of the applied and theoretical work on state capacity already shows some influence from public choice theory, the application of the economic approach to the study of political processes. These commonalities notwithstanding, this paper argues that public choice theory can offer further insights into this literature. In particular, the public choice approach can help illuminate concepts such as those of ‘state capacity’ and ‘governance,’ which are often casually employed in the literature. It can also help us understand the interaction between state capacity and competitive pressures in the ‘market for governance’. Finally, insights from public choice can illuminate the causal nexus between investment in state capacity and economic development.

Keywords

State capacity Public choice Interjurisdictional competition Political property rights 

Notes

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank Peter J. Boettke, Peter T. Leeson, David Skarbek, Mark Koyama, William F. Shughart II, Paola Suarez, three anonymous referees, and participants at the Southern Economic Association and Public Choice Society meetings for comments and suggestions. I am solely responsible for all remaining errors.

References

  1. Acemoglu, D. (2003). Why not a political Coase theorem? Social conflict, commitment, and politics. Journal of Comparative Economics, 31(4), 620–652.Google Scholar
  2. Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2001). The colonial origins of comparative development: An empirical investigation. American Economic Review, 91(5), 1369–1401.Google Scholar
  3. Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2005). Institutions as a fundamental cause of long-run growth. In P. Aghion & S. Durlauf (Eds.), Handbook of economic growth (Vol. 1, pp. 385–472). Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
  4. Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2001). A theory of political transitions. American Economic Review, 91(4), 938–963.Google Scholar
  5. Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2005). Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  6. Acemoglu, D., & Wolitzky, A. (2018). A theory of equality before the law. National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
  7. Acharya, A. & Lee, A. (2018). Economic foundations of the territorial state system. American Journal of Political Science, forthcoming.Google Scholar
  8. Aghion, P., Jaravel, X., Persson, T., & Rouzet, D. (2018). Education and military rivalry. Journal of the European Economic Association, forthcoming.Google Scholar
  9. Alesina, A., & Reich, B. (2016). Nation-building, National Bureau of Economic Research. Google Scholar
  10. Alesina, A., & Spolaore, E. (1997). On the number and size of nations. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(4), 1027–1056.Google Scholar
  11. Allen, D. W., & Barzel, Y. (2009). The evolution of criminal law and police during the pre-modern era. The Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 27(3), 540–567.Google Scholar
  12. Backhaus, J., & Wagner, R. E. (1987). The cameralists: A public choice perspective. Public Choice, 53(1), 3–20.Google Scholar
  13. Bardhan, P. (2016). State and development: The need for a reappraisal of the current literature. Journal of Economic Literature, 54(3), 862–892.Google Scholar
  14. Barzel, Y. (1997). Economic analysis of property rights. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  15. Barzel, Y. (2002). A theory of the state: economic rights, legal rights, and the scope of the state. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  16. Batchelder, R. W., & Freudenberger, H. (1983). On the rational origins of the modern centralized state. Explorations in Economic History, 20(1), 1.Google Scholar
  17. Batchelder, R. W., & Sanchez, N. (2013). The encomienda and the optimizing imperialist: an interpretation of Spanish imperialism in the Americas. Public Choice, 156(1–2), 45–60.Google Scholar
  18. Baumol, W. J. (1990). Entrepreneurship: Productive, unproductive, and destructive. Journal of Political Economy, 98((5 Part 1)), 893–921.Google Scholar
  19. Besley, T. (2007). The new political economy. Economic Journal, 117(524), F570–F587.Google Scholar
  20. Besley, T. (2011). Pathologies of the state. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 80(2), 339–350.Google Scholar
  21. Besley, T., & Coate, S. (1997). An economic model of representative democracy. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(1), 85–114.Google Scholar
  22. Besley, T., & Persson, T. (2008). Wars and state capacity. Journal of the European Economic Association, 6(2–3), 522–530.Google Scholar
  23. Besley, T., & Persson, T. (2009). The origins of state capacity: Property rights, taxation, and politics. American Economic Review, 99(4), 1218–1244.Google Scholar
  24. Besley, T., & Persson, T. (2010). State capacity, conflict, and development. Econometrica, 78(1), 1–34.Google Scholar
  25. Besley, T., & Persson, T. (2013). Taxation and development. Handbook of public economics (Vol. 5, pp. 51–110). Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
  26. Boettke, P. J., & Piano, E. E. (2019). Public choice and libertarianism. In R. Congleton, B. N. Grofman, & S. Voigt (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of public choice. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  27. Bonney, R. (1995). Economic systems and state finance: The origins of the modern state in Europe 13th to 18th centuries. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  28. Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. M. (1980). The power to tax: Analytic foundations of a fiscal constitution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  29. Brennan, G., & Tullock, G. (1982). An economic theory of military tactics: Methodological individualism at war. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 3(2–3), 225–242.Google Scholar
  30. Buchanan, J. M. (1965). An economic theory of clubs. Economica, 32(125), 1–14.Google Scholar
  31. Buchanan, J. M. (1987). The constitution of economic policy. The American Economic Review, 77(3), 243–250.Google Scholar
  32. Bueno de Mesquita, E. D. (2018). Territorial conflict and endogenous rents. The Journal of Politics, forthcoming.Google Scholar
  33. Candela, R., & Geloso, V. (2018). Trade or raid: Acadian settlers and native Indians Before 1755. Working paper.Google Scholar
  34. Cowen, T. (1990). Economic effects of a conflict-prone world order. Public Choice, 64(2), 121–134.Google Scholar
  35. Cox, G. W. (2017). Political institutions, economic liberty, and the great divergence. The Journal of Economic History, 77(3), 724–755.Google Scholar
  36. Day, W. R., Jr., (2002). The population of Florence before the Black Death: survey and synthesis. Journal of Medieval History, 28(2), 93–129.Google Scholar
  37. De Long, J. B., & Shleifer, A. (1993). Princes and merchants: European city growth before the industrial revolution. The Journal of Law and Economics, 36(2), 671–702.Google Scholar
  38. Demsetz, H. (1967). Toward a theory of property rights. American Economic Review, 62, 347–359.Google Scholar
  39. Dincecco, M. (2011). Political transformations and public finances: Europe, 1650–1913. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  40. Dincecco, M. (2015). The rise of effective states in Europe. The Journal of Economic History, 75(3), 901–918.Google Scholar
  41. Dincecco, M., & Onorato, M. G. (2016). Military conflict and the rise of urban Europe. Journal of Economic Growth, 21(3), 259–282.Google Scholar
  42. Dincecco, M., & Wang, Y. (2018). Violent conflict and political development over the long run: China versus Europe. Annual Review of Political Science, 21, 341–358.Google Scholar
  43. Dittmar, J., & Meisenzahl, R. R. (2016). State capacity and public goods: Institutional change, human capital, and growth in early modern Germany. Working paper.Google Scholar
  44. Ekelund, R. B., Jr., Hébert, R. F., & Tollison, R. D. (2002). An economic analysis of the Protestant Reformation. Journal of Political Economy, 110(3), 646–671.Google Scholar
  45. Ekelund, R. B., Tollison, R. D., Anderson, G. M., Hébert, R. F., & Davidson, A. B. (1996). Sacred trust: The medieval church as an economic firm. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  46. Friedman, D. (1977). A theory of the size and shape of nations. Journal of Political Economy, 85(1), 59–77.Google Scholar
  47. Geloso, V., & Salter, A. W. (2018). State capacity and economic development: Causal mechanism or correlative filter? Working paper.Google Scholar
  48. Greif, A. (2000). The fundamental problem of exchange: A research agenda in historical institutional analysis. European Review of Economic History, 4(3), 251–284.Google Scholar
  49. Hayek, F. A. (1945). The use of knowledge in society. The American Economic Review, 35(4), 519–530.Google Scholar
  50. Hendrickson, J. R., Salter, A. W., & Albrecht, B. C. (2018). Preventing plunder: Military technology, capital accumulation, and economic growth. Journal of Macroeconomics, forthcoming.Google Scholar
  51. Hirshleifer, J. (1994). The dark side of the force. Economic Inquiry, 32(1), 1–10.Google Scholar
  52. Johnson, N. D., & Koyama, M. (2014a). Tax farming and the origins of state capacity in England and France. Explorations in Economic History, 51, 1–20.Google Scholar
  53. Johnson, N. D., & Koyama, M. (2014b). Taxes, lawyers, and the decline of witch trials in France. The Journal of Law and Economics, 57(1), 77–112.Google Scholar
  54. Johnson, N. D., & Koyama, M. (2017). States and economic growth: Capacity and constraints. Explorations in Economic History, 64, 1–20.Google Scholar
  55. Jones, E. (2003). The European miracle: Environments, economies and geopolitics in the history of Europe and Asia. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  56. Koyama, M. (2012). Prosecution associations in industrial revolution England: Private providers of public goods? The Journal of Legal Studies, 41(1), 95–130.Google Scholar
  57. Koyama, M. (2014). The law and economics of private prosecutions in industrial revolution England. Public Choice, 159(1–2), 277–298.Google Scholar
  58. Koyama, M., Moriguchi, C., & Sng, T. H. (2018). Geopolitics and Asia’s little divergence: A comparative analysis of state building in China and Japan after 1850. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, forthcoming.Google Scholar
  59. Kurrild-Klitgaard, P., & Svendsen, G. T. (2003). Rational bandits: Plunder, public goods, and the Vikings. Public Choice, 117(3–4), 255–272.Google Scholar
  60. Lane, F. C. (1973). Venice: A maritime republic. Baltimore: JHU Press.Google Scholar
  61. Latzko, D. A. (1993). The Concept of “Military Economies of Scale”. Explorations in Economic History, 30(4), 470–484.Google Scholar
  62. Leeson, P. T. (2007a). Better off stateless: Somalia before and after government collapse. Journal of Comparative Economics, 35(4), 689–710.Google Scholar
  63. Leeson, P. T. (2007b). Efficient anarchy. Public Choice, 130(1–2), 41–53.Google Scholar
  64. Leeson, P. T. (2009). The laws of lawlessness. The Journal of Legal Studies, 38(2), 471–503.Google Scholar
  65. Leeson, P. T. (2012). Ordeals. The Journal of Law and Economics, 55(3), 691–714.Google Scholar
  66. Leeson, P. T., & Russ, J. W. (2018). Witch trials. The Economic Journal, 128(613), 2066–2105.Google Scholar
  67. Leeson, P. T., & Williamson, C. R. (2009). Anarchy and development: An application of the theory of second best. The Law and Development Review, 2(1), 77–96.Google Scholar
  68. Lopez, R. S. (1976). The Commercial revolution of the Middle Ages (pp. 950–1350). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  69. Martin, A. G., & Ruhland, J. (2018). Politics as exchange in the Byzantine Empire. Working paper.Google Scholar
  70. Martines, L. (1988). Power and imagination: City-states in Renaissance Italy. London: Taylor & Francis.Google Scholar
  71. Mayshar, J., Moav, O., Neeman, Z., & Pascali, L. (2018). The emergence of hierarchies and states: Productivity vs. appropriability. Working paper.Google Scholar
  72. McBride, M., Milante, G., & Skaperdas, S. (2011). Peace and war with endogenous state capacity. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 55(3), 446–468.Google Scholar
  73. McGuire, M. C., & Olson, M. (1996). The economics of autocracy and majority rule: the invisible hand and the use of force. Journal of Economic Literature, 34(1), 72–96.Google Scholar
  74. Monson, A., & Scheidel, W. (Eds.). (2015). Fiscal regimes and the political economy of premodern states. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  75. North, D. C. (1979). A framework for analyzing the state in economic history. Explorations in Economic History, 16(3), 249–259.Google Scholar
  76. North, D. C., & Thomas, R. P. (1973). The rise of the western world: A new economic history. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  77. North, D. C., Wallis, J. J., & Weingast, B. R. (2009). Violence and social orders: A conceptual framework for interpreting recorded human history. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  78. North, D. C., & Weingast, B. R. (1989). Constitutions and commitment: the evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. The Journal of Economic History, 49(4), 803–832.Google Scholar
  79. O’Brien, P. (2011). The nature and historical evolution of an exceptional fiscal state and its possible significance for the precocious commercialization and industrialization of the British economy from Cromwell to Nelson. The Economic History Review, 64(2), 408–446.Google Scholar
  80. Olson, M. (1993). Dictatorship, democracy, and development. American Political Science Review, 87(3), 567–576.Google Scholar
  81. Piano, E. E. (2017). Free riders: The economics and organization of outlaw motorcycle gangs. Public Choice, 171(3–4), 283–301.Google Scholar
  82. Powell, B., & Stringham, E. P. (2009). Public choice and the economic analysis of anarchy: A survey. Public Choice, 140(3–4), 503–538.Google Scholar
  83. Riker, W. H. (1990). Political science and rational choice. Perspectives on positive political economy (pp. 163–181). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  84. Salter, A. W. (2015). Sovereignty as exchange of political property rights. Public Choice, 165(1–2), 79–96.Google Scholar
  85. Salter, A. W. (2018). Private prerogative, public purpose: Public entrepreneurship and management in frederick the Great’s Anti-Machiavel. Working paper.Google Scholar
  86. Salter, A. W., & Young, A. T. (2018). Polycentric sovereignty: The medieval constitution, governance quality, and the wealth of nations. Social Science Quarterly, forthcoming.Google Scholar
  87. Schulze, W. (1995). The emergence and consolidation of the “tax state”: The sixteenth century. In R. Bonney (Ed.), Economic systems and state finance. The origins of the modern state in Europe 13th to 18th centuries (pp. 261–280). Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  88. Scott, J. C. (2017). Against the grain: A deep history of the earliest states. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  89. Shughart, W. F. (2018). Gordon Tullock’s critique of the common law. The Independent Review, 23(2), 209–227.Google Scholar
  90. Spruyt, H. (1994). Institutional selection in international relations: state anarchy as order. International Organization, 48(4), 527–557.Google Scholar
  91. Stasavage, D. (2002). Credible commitment in early modern Europe: North and Weingast revisited. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 18(1), 155–186.Google Scholar
  92. Stasavage, D. (2011). States of credit: Size, power, and the development of European polities (Vol. 35). Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  93. Tideman, T. N., & Tullock, G. (1976). A new and superior process for making social choices. Journal of Political Economy, 84(6), 1145–1159.Google Scholar
  94. Tiebout, C. M. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal of Political Economy, 64(5), 416–424.Google Scholar
  95. Tilly, C. (1990). Coercion, capital, and European states, AD 990. Cambridge: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
  96. Tullock, G. (1974). The social dilemma: The economics of war and revolution. Blacksburg: University Publications.Google Scholar
  97. Vahabi, M. (2011). Appropriation, violent enforcement, and transaction costs: A critical survey. Public Choice, 147(1–2), 227–253.Google Scholar
  98. Volckart, O. (2000). State building by bargaining for monopoly rents. Kyklos, 53(3), 265–291.Google Scholar
  99. Volckart, O. (2002). No utopia: Government without territorial monopoly in medieval central Europe. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 158(2), 325–343.Google Scholar
  100. Weingast, B. R. (1995). The economic role of political institutions: Market-preserving federalism and economic development. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 11(1), 1–31.Google Scholar
  101. Young, A. T. (2015). From Caesar to Tacitus: Changes in early Germanic governance circa 50 BC-50 AD. Public Choice, 164(3–4), 357–378.Google Scholar
  102. Young, A. T. (2016). What does it take for a roving bandit settle down? Theory and an illustrative history of the Visigoths. Public Choice, 168(1–2), 75–102.Google Scholar
  103. Zorzi, A. (2004). The popolo. In J. M. Najemy (Ed.), Italy in the Age of the Renaissance: 1300–1550. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC, part of Springer Nature 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.George Mason UniversityFairfaxUSA

Personalised recommendations