Public Choice

, Volume 164, Issue 3–4, pp 217–234 | Cite as

The Logic of Collective Action and beyond

Article

Abstract

This article provides an overview of Mancur Olson’s Logic of Collective Action and its impact on Olson’s subsequent work. It also suggests that the implications of his simple, elegant, theory have not yet been fully worked out. To illustrate this point, the second half of the essay demonstrates that the number of privileged and latent groups and their costs in a given society are not entirely determined by economic factors or group size alone. Politics, technology, and culture also matter.

Keywords

Mancur Olson Collective action Politics and effects of interest groups Cost of collective action Culture and interest groups Rent-seeking 

References

  1. Alchian, A. A., & Demsetz, H. (1972). Production, information costs, and economic organization. American Economic Review, 62, 777–795.Google Scholar
  2. Axelrod, R. (1984). The evolution of cooperation. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
  3. Axelrod, R., & Hamilton, W. D. (1981). The evolution of cooperation. Science, 27, 1390–1396.MathSciNetCrossRefADSGoogle Scholar
  4. Becker, G. S. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98, 371–400.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Bentley, A. (1908). The process of government. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  6. Besley, T., & Persson, T. (2009). The origins of state capacity: Property rights, taxation, and politics. American Economic Review, 99, 1218–1244.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Brennan, G., & Hamlin, A. (1998). Expressive voting and electoral equilibrium. Public Choice, 95, 149–172.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Buchanan, J. M. (1965). An economic theory of clubs. Economica, 32, 1–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Buchanan, J. M., & Congleton, R. D. (1998). Power by principle not privilege: Toward nondiscriminatory democracy. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  10. Congleton, R. D. (1991). Ideological conviction and persuasion in the rent-seeking society. Journal of Public Economics, 44, 65–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Congleton, R. D. (2011). Perfecting parliament: Constitutional reform, liberalism, and the rise of Western democracy. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  12. Congleton, R. D., & Hillman, A. L. (2015). Companion to the political economy of rent seeking. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Congleton, R. D., & Lee, S. (2009). Efficient mercantilism? Revenue-maximizing monopolization policies as Ramsey taxation. European Journal of Political Economy, 25, 102–114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (1996). The theory of externalities: Public goods, and club goods (2nd ed.). Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. De Tocqueville, A. (1835). Democracy in America. (An uncopyrighted Kindle version of the Reeves translation is available from Amazon.com).Google Scholar
  16. Fukuyama, F. (1995). Trust: The social virtues and the creation of prosperity. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
  17. Giddens, A. (1984). The constitution of society. Berkley, CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
  18. Harberger, A. (1954). Monopoly and resource allocation. American Economic Review, 44, 77–87.Google Scholar
  19. Heckelman, J. C., & Coates, D. (Eds.). (2003). Collective choice: Essays in honor of Mancur Olson. Heidelberg: Springer.Google Scholar
  20. Hillman, A. L., & Katz, E. (1987). Hierarchical structure and the social costs of bribes and transfers. Journal of Public Economics, 34, 129–142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Krueger, A. O. (1974). The political economy of the rent-seeking society. American Economic Review, 64, 291–303.Google Scholar
  22. McGuire, M. C. (1998). Mancur Lloyd Olson, Jr. 1932–98, Personal recollections. Eastern Economic Journal, 24, 252–263.Google Scholar
  23. Mill, J. S. (1873). Autobiography. London: Longmans, Green, Reader, and Dyer.Google Scholar
  24. Mueller, D. C. (2009). Reason, religion, and democracy. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Murphy, K. M., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1993). Why is rent seeking so costly to growth? American Economic Review, 83, 409–414.Google Scholar
  26. North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, institutional change, and economic performance. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Olson, M. (1963). The economics of wartime shortage: A history of British food shortages in the Napoleonic War and World Wars I and II. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
  28. Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action: Public goods and the theory of groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  29. Olson, M. (1982). The rise and decline of nations: Economic growth, stagflation, and social rigidities. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  30. Olson, M. (1990). How bright are the northern lights? Some questions about Sweden. Lund: Institute of Economic Research.Google Scholar
  31. Olson, M. (1993). Dictatorship, democracy and development. American Political Science Review, 87, 567–576.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Olson, M. (1996). Big bills left on the sidewalk: Why some nations are rich and others poor. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10, 2–24.Google Scholar
  33. Olson, M. (2000). Power and prosperity: Outgrowing communist and capitalist dictatorships. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
  34. Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Pecorino, P. (2015). Olson’s Logic of Collective Action at fifty. Public Choice, 162, 243–262.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Piketty, T. (2014). Capital in the twenty-first century. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Riker, W. H. (1962). The theory of political coalitions. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  38. Rowley, C. K. (2014). Public choice: the origins and development of a research program. In M. Reksulak, L. Razzolini, & W. F. Shughart II (Eds.), The Elgar companion to public choice (2nd ed.). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
  39. Sandler, T. (1992). Collective action: Theory and applications. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
  40. Truman, D. (1951). The governmental process. New York: Alfred A. Knopf.Google Scholar
  41. Tullock, G. (1967). The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies, and theft. Economic Inquiry, 5, 224–232.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Vanberg, V., & Congleton, R. D. (1992). Rationality, morality, and exit. American Political Science Review, 86, 418–431.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Wagner, R. E. (1966). Pressure groups and political entrepreneurs: A review article. Papers on Non-Market Decision Making, (Public Choice), 1, 161–170.Google Scholar
  44. Weber, M. (1905/2002). The Protestant ethic and the spirit of capitalism. New York: Penguin Classics.Google Scholar
  45. Wilson, E. O. (2014). The meaning of human existence. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
  46. Wilson, B., Jaworski, T., Shurter, K. E., & Smyth, A. (2012). The ecological and civil mainsprings of property: An experimental economic history of whalers’ rules of capture. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 28, 617–656.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Wintrobe, R. (1998). The political economy of dictatorship. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media New York 2015

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Department of EconomicsWest Virginia UniversityMorgantownUSA

Personalised recommendations