Public Choice

, Volume 162, Issue 3–4, pp 287–305 | Cite as

Anarchy, self-governance, and legal titling

Article

Abstract

Scholars and policymakers prescribe legal titling to improve prospects for economic development and political order. However, a public choice literature exists that has long recognized that self-governance often works well and that the state may not be able to improve upon local economic institutions at reasonable cost. Although the implication that legal titling should proceed with caution is seemingly straightforward, the literature on legal titling does not take anarchy seriously as a policy option. In addition, there is a public choice literature that presumes the state is the most important source of property rights. This essay fills this gap in the property rights literature by applying the concept of “efficient anarchy” to legal titling in Afghanistan. Original fieldwork evidence from rural Afghanistan suggests that anarchy of land governance is a better option than legal titling. The essay concludes by opening up the black box of state building by explaining why it often makes sense to sequence improvements in political capacity and political constraints prior to investing in legal titling.

Keywords

Property rights Legal titling Governance Anarchy Afghanistan Post-conflict reconstruction 

JEL Classification

H1 K1 O2 

References

  1. Acemoglu, D., & Jackson, M. O. (2014). Social norms and the enforcement of laws. National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
  2. Acemoglu, D., Reed, T., & Robinson, J. A. (2014). Chiefs: Economic development and elite control of civil society in Sierra Leone. Journal of Political Economy, 122(2), 319–368.Google Scholar
  3. Albertus, M., & Kaplan, O. (2013). Land reform as a counterinsurgency policy: Evidence from Colombia. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 57(2), 198–231.Google Scholar
  4. Alden Wily, L. (2003). Land relations in Bamyan Province: Findings from a 15 village case study. Kabul: Afghanistan Research and Evaluation Unit.Google Scholar
  5. Alden Wily, L. (2009). Looking for peace on the pastures: Rural land relations in Afghanistan. Kabul: Afghanistan Research and Evaluation Unit.Google Scholar
  6. Alden Wily, L. (2013). Land, people, and the state in Afghanistan. Kabul: Afghanistan Research and Evaluation Unit (AREU).Google Scholar
  7. Alston, L. J., Libecap, G. D., & Mueller, B. (1999). Titles, conflict, and land use: The development of property rights and land reform on the Brazilian Amazon frontier. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
  8. Anderson, J. (1978). There are no khāns anymore: Economic development and social change in tribal Afghanistan. Middle East Journal, 32(2), 167–183.Google Scholar
  9. Anderson, T. L., & Hill, P. J. (1990). The race for property rights. Journal of Law and Economics, 33, 177–197.Google Scholar
  10. Anderson, T. L., & Hill, P. J. (2002). Cowboys and contracts. The Journal of Legal Studies, 31(S2), S489–S514.Google Scholar
  11. Anderson, T. L., & Hill, P. J. (2004). The not so wild, wild west: Property rights on the frontier. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
  12. Andrews, M. (2013). The limits of institutional reform in development: Changing rules for realistic solutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  13. Arruñada, B. (2012). Institutional foundations of impersonal exchange: Theory and policy of contractual registries. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  14. Arruñada, B. (2014). Registries. Man and the Economy, 1(2), 209–230.Google Scholar
  15. Asia Foundation. (2011). A survey of the Afghan people. Asia Foundation.Google Scholar
  16. Baldwin, K. (2013). Why vote with the chief? Political connections and public goods provision in Zambia. American Journal of Political Science, 57(4), 794–809.Google Scholar
  17. Barfield, T. J. (2008). Culture and custom in nation-building: Law in Afghanistan. Maine Law Review, 60, 347.Google Scholar
  18. Barfield, T. J. (2010). Afghanistan: A cultural and political history. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  19. Barfield, T. J., Nojumi, N., & Thier, J. A. (2011). The clash of two goods: State and non-state dispute resolution in Afghanistan. In D. Isser (Ed.), Customary justice and the rule of law in war-torn societies. Washington, D.C: United States Institute of Peace.Google Scholar
  20. Barzel, Y. (1989). Economic analysis of property rights. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  21. Batson, D. E. (2008). Registering the human terrain: A valuation of cadastre. Washington: DTIC Document.Google Scholar
  22. Batson, D. E. (2013). Snow leopards and cadastres: Rare sightings in post-conflict Afghanistan. In J. Unruh & R. Williams (Eds.), Land and Post-Conflict Peacebuilding (pp. 245–65).Google Scholar
  23. Beath, A., Christia, F., & Enikolopov, R. (2013). Empowering women: Evidence from a field experiment in Afghanistan. American Political Science Review, 107(3), 540–557.Google Scholar
  24. Berkowitz, D., Pistor, K., & Richard, J.-F. (2001). Economic development, legality, and the transplant effect. European Economic Review, 47(1), 165–195.Google Scholar
  25. Berkowitz, D., Pistor, K., & Richard, J.-F. (2003). The transplant effect. American Journal of Comparative Law, 51, 163.Google Scholar
  26. Boone, C. (2013). Property and political order in Africa: Land rights and the structure of politics. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  27. Bromley, D. W. (2006). Sufficient reason: Volitional pragmatism and the meaning of economic institutions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  28. Bromley, D. W. (2009). Formalising property relations in the developing world: The wrong prescription for the wrong malady. Land Use Policy, 26(1), 20–27.Google Scholar
  29. Bromley, D. W., & Anderson, G. (2012). Vulnerable people, vulnerable states: Redefining the development challenge. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
  30. Clay, K. B., & Wright, G. (2005). Order without law? Property rights during the California gold rush. Explorations in Economic History, 42(2), 155–183.Google Scholar
  31. Coburn, N. (2011). Bazaar politics: Power and pottery in an Afghan market town. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
  32. Commons, J. R. (1924). Legal foundations of capitalism. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  33. Coyne, C. J. (2008a). After war: The political economy of exporting democracy. Palo Alto: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
  34. Coyne, C. J. (2008b). The politics of bureaucracy and the failure of post-war reconstruction. Public Choice, 135(1–2), 11–22.Google Scholar
  35. Coyne, C. J., & Boettke, P. J. (2009). The problem of credible commitment in reconstruction. Journal of Institutional Economics, 5(1), 1.Google Scholar
  36. De Soto, H. (2000). The mystery of capital: Why capitalism triumphs in the West and fails everywhere else. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
  37. Deininger, K., & Feder, G. (2009). Land registration, governance, and development: Evidence and implications for policy. The World Bank Research Observer, 24(2), 233–266.Google Scholar
  38. Edwards, D. B. (2002). Before Taliban: Genealogies of the Afghan jihad. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
  39. Ellickson, R. C. (1991). Order without law: How neighbors settle disputes. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  40. Fearon, J. D., & Laitin, D. D. (2011). Sons of the soil, migrants, and civil war. World Development, 39(2), 199–211.Google Scholar
  41. Field, E. (2005). Property rights and investment in urban slums. Journal of the European Economic Association, 3(2–3), 279–290.Google Scholar
  42. Flores, T. E., & Nooruddin, I. (2012). The effect of elections on postconflict peace and reconstruction. The Journal of Politics, 1(1), 1–13.Google Scholar
  43. Foschini, F. (2013). Land grabs in Afghanistan: Deh Sabz, the new and the old. Afghanistan Analysts Network.Google Scholar
  44. Fukuyama, F. (2013). What is governance? Governance, 26(3), 347–368.Google Scholar
  45. Fukuyama, F. (2014). Political order and political decay: From the industrial revolution to the globalization of democracy. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  46. Galiani, S., & Schargrodsky, E. (2010). Property rights for the poor: Effects of land titling. Journal of Public Economics, 94(9), 700–729.Google Scholar
  47. Gehlbach, S., & Keefer, P. (2011). Investment without democracy: Ruling-party institutionalization and credible commitment in autocracies. Journal of Comparative Economics, 39(2), 123–139.Google Scholar
  48. Giustozzi, A., Franco, C., & Baczko, A. (2012). Shadow justice: How the Taliban run their judiciary. Kabul, Afghanistan: Integrity Watch Afghanistan.Google Scholar
  49. Government of the Islamic Republic of Afgahanistan. Central Statistics Organization. http://cso.gov.af/en.
  50. Greif, A. (2005). Commitment, coercion and markets: The nature and dynamics of institutions supporting exchange. In C. Ménard & M. M. Shirley (Eds.), Handbook of new institutional economics (pp. 727–786). Dordrecht: Springer.Google Scholar
  51. Greif, A. (2006). Institutions and the path to the modern economy: Lessons from medieval trade. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  52. Hadfield, G. K., & Weingast, B. R. (2012). What is law? A coordination model of the characteristics of legal order. Journal of Legal Analysis, 4(2), 471–514.Google Scholar
  53. Hadfield, G. K., & Weingast, B. R. (2013). Law without the state. Journal of Law and Courts, 1(1), 3–34.Google Scholar
  54. Hanifi, S. M. (2011). Connecting histories in Afghanistan: Market relations and state formation on a colonial frontier. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
  55. Herbst, J. (2000). States and power in Africa: Comparative lessons in authority and control. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  56. Hodgson, G. M. (2009). On the institutional foundations of law: the insufficiency of custom and private ordering. Journal of Economic Issues, 43(1), 143–166.Google Scholar
  57. Kakar, H. (1979). Government and society in Afghanistan: The reign of Amir’Abd al-Rahman Khan. Austin, TX: University of Texas Press.Google Scholar
  58. Kerekes, C. B., & Williamson, C. R. (2008). Unveiling de Soto’s mystery: Property rights, capital formation, and development. Journal of Institutional Economics, 4(3), 299.Google Scholar
  59. Kerekes, C. B., & Williamson, C. R. (2010). Propertyless in Peru, even with a government land title. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 69(3), 1011–1033.Google Scholar
  60. Knight, J., & North, D. C. (1997). Explaining the complexity of institutional change. The political economy of property rights: Institutional change and credibility in the reform of centrally planned economies (pp. 349–354). New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  61. Landa, J. T. (1981). A theory of the ethnically homogeneous middleman group: An institutional alternative to contract law. The Journal of Legal Studies, 10, 349–362.Google Scholar
  62. Leeson, P. T. (2006). Efficient anarchy. Public Choice, 130(1–2), 41–53.Google Scholar
  63. Leeson, P. T. (2007a). Anarchy, monopoly, and predation. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 163(3), 467–482.Google Scholar
  64. Leeson, P. T. (2007b). Better off stateless: Somalia before and after government collapse. Journal of Comparative Economics, 35(4), 689–710.Google Scholar
  65. Leeson, P. T. (2011). Government, clubs, and constitutions. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 80(2), 301–308.Google Scholar
  66. Leeson, P. T. (2014). Anarchy unbound: Why self-governance works better than you think. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  67. Leeson, P. T., & Coyne, C. J. (2012). Sassywood. Journal of Comparative Economics, 40(4), 608–620.Google Scholar
  68. Libecap, G. D. (1989). Contracting for property rights. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  69. Libecap, G. D. (2007). The assignment of property rights on the western frontier: Lessons for contemporary environmental and resource policy. Journal of Economic History, 67(2), 257.Google Scholar
  70. Lund, C. (2008). Local politics and the dynamics of property in Africa. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  71. Malkasian, C. (2013). War comes to Garmser: Thirty years of conflict on the Afghan frontier. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  72. Menkhaus, K. (2007). Governance without government in Somalia: Spoilers, state building, and the politics of coping. International Security, 31, 74–106.Google Scholar
  73. Milgrom, P. R., & North, D. C. (1990). The role of institutions in the revival of trade: The law merchant, private judges, and the champagne fairs. Economics and Politics, 2(1), 1–23.Google Scholar
  74. Mukhopadhyay, D. (2013). Warlords, strongman governors and state building in Afghanistan. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  75. Murtazashvili, I. (2013). The political economy of the American frontier. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  76. Murtazashvili, J. (2014). Informal federalism: Self-governance and power sharing in Afghanistan. Publius: The Journal of Federalism, 44(2), 324–343.Google Scholar
  77. Murtazashvili, J. (2015). Informal order and the state in Afghanistan. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  78. Newell, R. S. (1972). The politics of Afghanistan. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
  79. North, D. C. (1981). Structure and change in economic history. New York: W. W. Norton & Company.Google Scholar
  80. North, D. C., & Thomas, R. P. (1973). The rise of the Western world: A new economic history. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  81. North, D. C., & Weingast, B. R. (1989). Constitutions and commitment: The evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. The Journal of Economic History, 49(4), 803–832.Google Scholar
  82. Olson, M. (1993). Dictatorship, democracy, and development. American Political Science Review, 87(3), 567–576.Google Scholar
  83. Onoma, A. K. (2009). The politics of property rights institutions in Africa. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  84. Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  85. Ostrom, E. (2005). Understanding institutional diversity. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  86. Peter, T. A. (2011, August 11). What may be a bigger threat to Afghanistan than insurgency? Land disputes. Christian Science Monitor.Google Scholar
  87. Powell, B., & Stringham, E. P. (2009). Public choice and the economic analysis of anarchy: A survey. Public Choice, 140(3–4), 503–538.Google Scholar
  88. Pritchett, L., Woolcock, M., & Andrews, M. (2013). Looking like a state: Techniques of persistent failure in state capability for implementation. The Journal of Development Studies, 49(1), 1–18.Google Scholar
  89. Rahman, A. (1900). The life of Abdur Rahman. Amir of Afghanistan: John Murray.Google Scholar
  90. Rashid, A. (2010). Taliban: Militant Islam, oil and fundamentalism in Central Asia. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  91. Riker, W. H., & Sened, I. (1991). A political theory of the origin of property rights: Airport slots. American Journal of Political Science, 35(4), 951–969.Google Scholar
  92. Riker, W. H., & Weimer, D. L. (1993). The economic and political liberalization of socialism: The fundamental problem of property rights. Social Philosophy and Policy, 10(02), 79–102.Google Scholar
  93. Riker, W. H., & Weimer, D. L. (1995). The political economy of transformation: Liberalization and property rights. Modern political economy: Old topics, new directions (pp. 80–107). New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  94. Roy, O. (1990). Islam and resistance in Afghanistan. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  95. Rubin, B. R. (2002). The fragmentation of Afghanistan: State formation and collapse in the international system. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  96. Safar, M. Y., & Stanfield, J. D. (2007). Cadastral survey in Afghanistan. Kabul: Asian Development Bank.Google Scholar
  97. Scott, J. C. (2009). The art of not being governed: An anarchist history of upland Southeast Asia. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  98. Scott, J. C. (2012). Two cheers for anarchism: Six easy pieces on autonomy, dignity, and meaningful work and play. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  99. Sediqi, R. (2013, June 3). Land grabbing a new concern for Afghanistan. Tolo News.Google Scholar
  100. Sened, I. (1997). The political institution of private property. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  101. Sjaastad, E., & Bromley, D. W. (1997). Indigenous land rights in Sub-Saharan Africa: Appropriation, security and investment demand. World Development, 25(4), 549–562.Google Scholar
  102. Skarbek, D. (2011). Governance and prison gangs. American Political Science Review, 105(04), 702–716.Google Scholar
  103. Skarbek, D. (2012). Prison gangs, norms, and organizations. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 82(1), 96–109.Google Scholar
  104. Stanfield, J. D., Murtazashvili, J. B., Safar, M. Y., & Salam, A. (2013). Community documentation of land tenure and its contribution to state-building in Afghanistan. In R. Williams & J. Unruh (Eds.), Land and post-conflict peacebuilding (pp. 265–285).Google Scholar
  105. Stanfield, J. D., Safar, Y., Salam, A., & Brick, J. (2010). Rangeland administration in (post) conflict conditions: The case of Afghanistan. In K. Deininger, C. Augustinus, S. Enmark, & P. Munro-Faure (Eds.), Innovations in land rights: Recognition, administration and governance (pp. 300–317). Washington: World Bank.Google Scholar
  106. Stringham, E. P. (2014). Extending the analysis of spontaneous market order to governance. Atlantic Economic Journal, 42(2), 171–180.Google Scholar
  107. Sugden, R. (1989). Spontaneous order. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 3, 85–97.Google Scholar
  108. Umbeck, J. (1977). A theory of contract choice and the California gold rush. Journal of Law and Economics, 20, 421.Google Scholar
  109. Weimer, D. L. (Ed.). (1997). The political economy of property rights: Institutional change and credibility in the reform of centrally planned economies. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  110. Weingast, B. R. (1995). The economic role of political institutions: Market-preserving federalism and economic development. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 11, 1.Google Scholar
  111. Williamson, C. R. (2009). Informal institutions rule: Institutional arrangements and economic performance. Public Choice, 139(3–4), 371–387.Google Scholar
  112. Williamson, C. R., & Kerekes, C. B. (2011). Securing private property: Formal versus informal institutions. Journal of Law and Economics, 54(3), 537–572.Google Scholar
  113. Williamson, C. R., & Mathers, R. L. (2011). Economic freedom, culture, and growth. Public Choice, 148(3–4), 313–335.Google Scholar
  114. Wintrobe, R. (1998). The political economy of dictatorship. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media New York 2014

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Graduate School of Public and International AffairsUniversity of PittsburghPittsburghUSA

Personalised recommendations