Public Choice

, Volume 159, Issue 1–2, pp 197–218

Location, location, location: the Davis-Hinich model of electoral competition

Article

Abstract

The Davis-Hinich multidimensional model of electoral competition is the foundation for a very broad set of models in economics, political science, public choice and political economy. This essay reviews some of these models and how they build on and extend the original Davis-Hinich model. It also presents a new extension that makes individual preferences endogenous to the electoral process. The essay concludes with a discussion of the positive and normative implications of endogenous preferences and then returns to the basic theme of the central importance of the early Davis-Hinich papers.

Keywords

Electoral competition Spatial models Endogenous preferences 

References

  1. Aldrich, J. H. (1983). A Downsian spatial model with party activism. American Political Science Review, 77(4), 974–990. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Alesina, A. (1988). Credibility and policy convergence in a two-party system with rational voters. The American Economic Review, 78(4), 796–805. Google Scholar
  3. American National Election Studies Data Center. http://electionstudies.org/studypages/download/datacenter_all.htm.
  4. Barr, J. L., & Davis, O. A. (1966). An elementary political and economic theory of the expenditures of local governments. Southern Economic Journal, 33(2), 149–165. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Bartels, L. M. (2002). Beyond the running tally: partisan bias in political perceptions. Political Behavior, 24(2), 117–150. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Black, D. (1958). The theory of committees and elections. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Google Scholar
  7. Black, D., & Newing, R. A. (1951). Committee decisions with complementary valuation. London: William Hodge. Google Scholar
  8. Bowen, H. R. (1943). The interpretation of voting in the allocation of economic resources. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 58(1), 27–48. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Calvert, R. l. (1985). Robustness of the multidimensional voting model: candidate motivations, uncertainty, and convergence. American Journal of Political Science, 29(1), 69–95. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Carmines, E. C., & Stimson, J. A. (1989). Issue evolution: race and the transformation of American politics. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Google Scholar
  11. Cohen, M. E., & Axelrod, R. (1984). Coping with complexity: the adaptive value of changing utility. American Economic Review, 74(1), 30–42. Google Scholar
  12. Cox, G. (1990). Centripetal and centrifugal incentives in electoral systems. American Journal of Political Science, 34, 905–935. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Cyert, R. M., & DeGroot, M. H. (1975). Adaptive utility. In R. H. Day & T. Groves (Eds.), Adaptive economic models. New York: Academic Press. Google Scholar
  14. Cyert, R. M., & DeGroot, M. H. (1987). In Bayesian analysis and uncertainty in economic theory. Totowa: Rowman and Littlefield. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Davidson, R., & MacKinnon, J. G. (1993). Estimation and inference in econometrics. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Google Scholar
  16. Davidson, R., & MacKinnon, J. G. (2004). Econometric theory and methods. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Google Scholar
  17. Davis, O. A., & Hinich, M. J. (1966). A mathematical model of policy formation in a democratic society. In J. L. Bernd (Ed.), Mathematical applications in political science, II (pp. 175–208). Dallas: Arnold Foundation Monographs. Google Scholar
  18. Davis, O. A., & Hinich, M. J. (1968). On the power and importance of the mean preference in a mathematical model of democratic choice. Public Choice, V, 59–72. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Davis, O. A., & Whinston, A. (1962). Externalities, welfare, and the theory of games. The Journal of Political Economy, 70(3), 241–262. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Davis, O. A., Dempster, M. A. H., & Wildavsky, A. (1966). A theory of the budgetary process. American Political Science Review, 60(3), 529–547. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Davis, O. A., Hinich, M. J., & Ordeshook, P. C. (1970). An expository development of a mathematical model of the electoral process. American Political Science Review, 64(2), 426–448. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Davis, O. A., DeGroot, M. H., & Hinich, M. J. (1972). Social preference orderings and majority rule. Econometrica, 40(1), 147–157. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Disch, L. (2011). Toward a mobilization conception of democratic representation. American Political Science Review, 105(1), 100–114. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper. Google Scholar
  25. Enelow, J. M., & Hinich, M. J. (1983). On Plott’s pairwise symmetry condition for majority rule equilibrium. Public Choice, 40(3), 317–321. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Erikson, R. S., & Romero, D. W. (1990). Candidate equilibrium and the behavioral model of the vote. American Political Science Review, 84, 1103–1126. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Franklin, C. H., & Jackson, J. E. (1983). The dynamics of party identification. American Political Science Review, 77(4), 957–973. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Gerber, E., & Jackson, J. E. (1993). Endogenous preferences and the study of institutions. American Political Science Review, 87(3), 639–656. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Grzymała-Busse, A. M. (2002). Redeeming the communist past. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Hinich, M. J., & Munger, M. C. (2008). The dynamics of issue introduction: a model based on the politics of ideology. Mathematical and Computer Modeling, 48, 1510–1518. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Holcombe, R. G. (1980). An empirical test of the median voter model. Economic Inquiry, 18(2), 260–274. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Hotelling, H. (1929). Stability in competition. Economic Journal, 39, 41–57. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Inman, R. P. (1978). Testing political economy’s ‘as if’ proposition: is the median voter really decisive? Public Choice, 33(4), 45–65. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Jackson, J. E. (1973). Intensities, preferences, and electoral politics. Social Science Research, 2(3), 231–246. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Jackson, J. E. (1999). Electoral competition with endogenous voter preferences. In K. Kollman, J. Miller, & S. E. Page (Eds.), Computational models in political economy (pp. 109–142). Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Google Scholar
  36. Jackson, J. E. (2013). The shrinking difference between spatial and valence issues. Discussion paper. Dept. of Political Science, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, MI. Google Scholar
  37. Jackson, J. E., & Kollman, K. (2010). A formulation of path dependence with an empirical example. Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 5(3), 257–289. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Jackson, J. E., & Kollman, K. (2011). Connecting micro and macro partisanship. Political Analysis, 19(4), 503–518. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Jackson, J. E., & Kollman, K. (2012). Modeling, measuring, and distinguishing path dependence, outcome dependence, and outcome independence. Political Analysis, 20(2), 157–174. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Jackson, J. E., Klich, J., & Poznańska, K. (2005). The political economy of Poland’s transition: new firms and reform governments. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Jackson, J. E., Mach, B. W., & Markowski, R. (2010). Party strategy and electoral competition in post-communist countries: evidence from Poland. Electoral Studies, 29(2), 199–209. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Jessee, S. A. (2009). Spatial voting in the 2004 presidential election. American Political Science Review, 103(1), 59–81. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Kessel, J. (1988). Presidential campaign politics. Chicago: The Dorsey Press. Google Scholar
  44. Kinder, D. R. (1986). Presidential character revisited. In R. Lau & D. O. Sears (Eds.), Political cognition (pp. 233–255). Hillsdale: Erlbaum. Google Scholar
  45. Kinder, D. R., Peters, M. D., Abelson, R. P., & Fiske, S. T. (1980). Presidential prototypes. Political Behavior, 2(4), 315–337. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  46. Kollman, K., Miller, J. H., & Page, S. E. (1992). Adaptive parties in spatial elections. American Political Science Review, 86(4), 929–937. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Lacy, D., & Paolino, P. (2010). Testing proximity versus directional voting using experiments. Electoral Studies, 29(3), 460–471. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. McCloskey, H., Hoffman, P. J., & O’Hara, R. (1960). Issue conflict and consensus among party leaders and followers. American Political Science Review, 54(2), 406–427. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. McKelvey, R. (1976). Intransitivities in multidimensional voting models and some implications for agenda control. Journal of Economic Theory, 12, 472–482. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. McKelvey, R., & Schofield, N. (1986). Structural instability and the core. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 15, 179–198. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Merrill, S. III, & Adams, J. (2002). Centrifugal incentives in multicandidate elections. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 14(3), 275–300. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Miller, W. E., & Jennings, M. K. (1986). Parties in transition. New York: Russell Sage Foundation. Google Scholar
  53. Peress, M. (2010). The spatial model with non-policy factors: a theory of policy motivated candidates. Social Choice & Welfare, 34(2), 265–294. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Plott, C. R. (1967). A notion of equilibrium and its possibility under majority rule. American Economic Review, 57(4), 787–806. Google Scholar
  55. Romer, T., & Rosenthal, H. (1979). The elusive median voter. Journal of Public Economics, 12(2), 143–170. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  56. Sanders, D., Clarke, H. D., Stewart, M. C., & Whiteley, P. (2008). The endogeneity of preferences: evidence from the 2005 British Election Study. Journal of Elections, Public Opinion & Parties, 18(4), 413–431. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  57. Sanders, D., Clarke, H. D., Stewart, M. C., & Whiteley, P. (2011). Downs, stokes and the dynamics of electoral choice. British Journal of Political Science, 41(2), 287–314. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  58. Schofield, N., & Miller, G. (2003). Activists and partisan realignment in the United States. American Political Science Review, 97(2), 245–260. Google Scholar
  59. Schofield, N., & Miller, G. (2007). Elections and activist coalitions in the United States. American Journal of Political Science, 51(3), 518–531. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  60. Stokes, D. E. (1963). Spatial models of party competition. American Political Science Review, 57(2), 368–377. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  61. Tomz, M., & Van Houweling, R. P. (2008). Candidate positioning and voter choice. American Political Science Review, 102(3), 303–318. Google Scholar
  62. Turnbull, G. K., & Djoundourian, S. S. (1994). The median voter hypothesis: evidence from general purpose local governments. Public Choice, 81(3–4), 223–240. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  63. Wittman, D. (1983). Candidate motivation: a synthesis of alternative theories. American Political Science Review, 77(1), 142–157. CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media New York 2012

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.University of MichiganAnn ArborUSA

Personalised recommendations