Public Choice

, Volume 148, Issue 1–2, pp 21–44 | Cite as

Election results and opportunistic policies: A new test of the rational political business cycle model

  • Toke S. Aidt
  • Francisco José Veiga
  • Linda Gonçalves Veiga
Article

Abstract

The literature on the rational PBC suggests that politicians systematically manipulate economic and fiscal conditions before elections to increase their chances of reelection. Most tests of this theory look for evidence of pre-election distortions in fiscal policy. We propose a new test that explores the two-way interaction between the magnitude of the opportunistic distortion and the margin of victory. The test is implemented using a large panel of Portuguese municipalities. The results show that opportunism leads to a larger win-margin for the incumbent and that incumbents behave more opportunistically when their win-margin is small. These results are consistent with the theoretical model.

Keywords

Vote and popularity functions Opportunism Rational political business cycles Local government System estimation Portugal 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Akhmedov, A., & Zhuravskaya, E. (2004). Opportunistic political cycles: test in a young democracy setting. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119, 1301–1338. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Alesina, A. (1987). Macroeconomic policy in a two-party system as a repeated game. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102, 651–678. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Alesina, A., Londregan, J., & Rosenthal, H. (1993). A model of the political economy of the United States. American Political Science Review, 87(1), 12–33. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Alt, J., & Lassen, D. (2006). Transparency, political polarization, and political budget cycles in OECD countries. American Journal of Political Science, 50(3), 530–550. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Besley, T., & Case, A. (2003). Political institutions and policy choices: evidence from the United States. Journal of Economic Literature, XLI(1), 7–73. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Blais, A., & Nadeau, R. (1992). The electoral budget cycle. Public Choice, 74, 389–403. Google Scholar
  7. Brender, A., & Drazen, A. (2005). Political budget cycles in new versus established democracies. Journal of Monetary Economics, 52(7), 1271–1295. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Brender, A., & Drazen, A. (2008). How do budget deficits and economic growth affect reelection prospects? Evidence from a large panel of countries. American Economic Review, 98(5), 2203–2220. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Carsey, T., & Wright, G. (1998). State and national factors in gubernatorial and senatorial elections. American Journal of Political Science, 42(3), 994–1002. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Carson, J., Engstrom, E., & Roberts, J. (2007). Candidate quality, the personal vote, and the incumbency advantage in Congress. American Political Science Review, 101(2), 289–301. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Cho, I.-K., & Kreps, D. (1987). Signaling games and stable equilibria. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102, 179–221. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. DGAL (1979–1983 and 1986–2001). Finanças Municipais. Direcção Geral das Autarquias Locais (DGAL), Lisbon. Google Scholar
  13. Drazen, A., & Eslava, M. (2010). Electoral manipulation via expenditure composition: theory and evidence. Journal of Development Economics, 92, 39–52. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Frey, B., & Schneider, F. (1978a). An empirical study of politico-economic interaction in the United States. Review of Economics and Statistics, 60, 174–183. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Frey, B., & Schneider, F. (1978b). A politico-economic model of the United Kingdom. Economic Journal, 88, 243–253. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Galli, E., & Rossi, S. (2002). Political budget cycles: the case of the Western German Länder. Public Choice, 110, 283–303. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Goodhart, C. A. E., & Bhansali, R. J. (1970). Political economy. Political Studies, 18, 43–106. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Grier, K. (2008). US presidential elections and real GDP growth, 1961–2004. Public Choice, 135, 337–352. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Hibbs, D. (1977). Political parties and macroeconomic policy. The American Political Science Review, 7, 1467–1487. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Hibbs, D. (1987). The political economy of industrial democracies. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Google Scholar
  21. Hibbs, D. (1992). Partisan theory after fifteen years. European Journal of Political Economy, 8, 361–373. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Kramer, G. H. (1971). Short-term fluctuations in US voting behavior, 1896–1964. American Political Science Review, 65, 131–143. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Levitt, S., & Wolfram, C. (1997). Decomposing the sources of incumbency advantage in the U.S. house. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 22, 45–60. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Mueller, J. E. (1970). Presidential popularity from Truman to Johnson. American Political Science Review, 64, 18–23. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Nordhaus, W. (1975). The political business cycle. Review of Economic Studies, 42, 169–190. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Paldam, M. (2004) Are vote and popularity functions economically correct? In C. K. Rowley & F. Schneider (Eds.), The encyclopedia of public choice (Vol. I, pp. 49–59). Norwell: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Google Scholar
  27. Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (1990). Political economics: explaining economic policy. Cambridge: MIT Press. Google Scholar
  28. Pettersson-Lidbom, P. (2001). An empirical investigation of the strategic use of debt. Journal of Political Economy, 109(3), 570–583. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Rogoff, K. (1990). Equilibrium political budget cycles. American Economic Review, 80, 21–36. Google Scholar
  30. Rogoff, K., & Sibert, A. (1988). Elections and macroeconomic policy cycles. Review of Economics Studies, 55, 1–16. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Rosenberg, J. (1992). Rationality and the political business cycle: the case of local government. Public Choice, 73, 71–81. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Seitz, H. (2000). Fiscal policy, deficits and politics of subnational governments: the case of the German Laender. Public Choice, 102, 183–218. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Shi, M., & Svensson, J. (2006). Political budget cycles: do they differ across countries and why? Journal of Public Economics, 90, 1367–1389. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Snyder, J. (1989). Election goals and the allocation of campaign resources. Econometrica, 57(3), 637–660. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Tompkins, M. (1984). The electoral fortunes of gubernatorial incumbents: 1947–1981. Journal of Politics, 46, 520–543. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Tuomala, M. (1990). Optimal income tax and redistribution. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Google Scholar
  37. Veiga, F. J., & Veiga, L. G. (2004a). Popularity functions, partisan effects and support in Parliament. Economics & Politics, 16(1), 101–115. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Veiga, F. J., & Veiga, L. G. (2004b). The determinants of vote intentions in Portugal. Public Choice, 118(3–4), 341–364. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Veiga, L. G., & Veiga, F. J. (2007). Political business cycles at the municipal level. Public Choice, 131(1–2), 45–64. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Vergne, C. (2009). Democracy, elections and allocation of public expenditures in developing countries. European Journal of Political Economy, 25(1), 63–77. CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2010

Authors and Affiliations

  • Toke S. Aidt
    • 1
  • Francisco José Veiga
    • 2
  • Linda Gonçalves Veiga
    • 2
  1. 1.Faculty of EconomicsUniversity of CambridgeCambridgeUK
  2. 2.Escola de Economia e GestãoUniversidade do Minho and NIPEBragaPortugal

Personalised recommendations