Advertisement

Public Choice

, Volume 140, Issue 1–2, pp 85–104 | Cite as

A basic tool set for a generalized directional model

  • Eric LinhartEmail author
  • Susumu Shikano
Article

Abstract

In political science, there are two classes of spatial models: those which are based on a distance logic and those which are based on a directional logic. This distinction can be found in terms of diverse topics, as voting theory, coalition theory or legislative politics. While Tsebelis (Br. J. Political Sci. 25:289–325, 1995) among others discussed implications of distance models, the respective counterparts for directional models have not been explicitly derived in the existing literature. We try to close this gap by discussing discrepancies between both kinds of models and derive some of the most relevant tools for analyses based on directional models.

Keywords

Spatial model Proximity models Directional models 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Adams, J., Bishin, B. G., & Dow, J. K. (2004). Representation in congressional campaigns: evidence for discounting/directional voting in U.S. Senate elections. The Journal of Politics, 66, 348–373. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Austen-Smith, D. (1996). Refinements of the heart. In N. J. Schofield (Ed.), Collective decision-making: social choice and political economy (pp. 221–236). Dordrecht: Kluwer. Google Scholar
  3. Austen-Smith, D., & Banks, J. (1988). Elections, coalitions, and legislative outcomes. American Political Science Review, 82, 405–422. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Baron, D. P., & Diermeier, D. (2001). Elections, governments, and parliaments in proportional representation systems. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116, 933–967. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Budge, I., Klingemann, H.-D., Volkens, A., & Bara, J. (2001). Mapping policy preferences: estimates for parties, electors, and governments 1945–1998. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Google Scholar
  6. Cooter, R. (1999). The strategic constitution. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Google Scholar
  7. De Swaan, A. (1973). Coalition theories and cabinet formations. Amsterdam: Elsevier. Google Scholar
  8. Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper. Google Scholar
  9. Enelow, J., & Hinich, M. J. (1984). The spatial theory of voting. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Google Scholar
  10. Grofman, B. (1985). The neglected role of the status quo in models of issue voting. The Journal of Politics, 47, 230–237. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Henning, C. H., Hinich, M. J., & Shikano, S. (2007). Proximity versus directional models of voting: different concepts but one theory. In M. J. Hinich & W. A. Barnett (Eds.), Topics in analytical political economy (pp. 117–138). Amsterdam: Elsevier. Google Scholar
  12. Herrmann, M. (2008). Moderat bevorzugt, extreme gewählt. Zum Zusammenhang von Präferenz und Wahlentscheidung in räumlichen Modellen sachfragenorientierten Wählens. Politische Vierteljahresschrift, 49, 20–45. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Lacy, D., & Paolino, P. (1998). Downsian voting and the separation of powers. American Journal of Political Science, 42, 1180–1199. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Laver, M., & Shepsle, K. (1996). Making and breaking governments. Cabinets and legislatures in parliamentary democracies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Google Scholar
  15. Kedar, O. (2005). When moderate voters prefer extreme parties: policy balancing in parliamentary elections. American Political Science Review, 99, 185–199. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Krehbiel, K. (1988). Spatial models of legislative choice. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 13, 259–319. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Lewis, J. B., & King, G. (1999). No evidence on directional vs. proximity voting. Political Analysis, 8, 21–33. Google Scholar
  18. Linhart, E., & Shikano, S. (2007). Die Generierung von Parteipositionen aus vorverschlü sselten Wahlprogrammen für die Bundesrepublik Deutschland (1949–2002). Mannheim: MZES Working Paper No. 98. Google Scholar
  19. Macdonald, S. E., Rabinowitz, G., & Listhaug, O. (1998). On attempting to rehabilitate the proximity model: sometimes the patient just can’t be helped. The Journal of Politics, 60, 653–690. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Matthews, S. A. (1979). A simple direction model of electoral competition. Public Choice, 34, 141–156. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Merrill, S., & Grofman, B. (1999). A unified theory of voting. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Google Scholar
  22. Platt, G., Poole, K. T., & Rosenthal, H. (1992). Directional and Euclidean theories of voting behavior: a legislative comparison. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 17, 561–572. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Poole, K. T. (2005). Spatial models of parliamentary voting. New York: Cambridge University Press. Google Scholar
  24. Poole, K. T., & Rosenthal, H. (1997). Congress: a political economic history of roll call voting. New York: Oxford University Press. Google Scholar
  25. Rabinowitz, G., & Macdonald, S. E. (1989). A directional theory of issue voting. American Political Science Review, 83, 93–121. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Schofield, N. J. (1978). Generalised bargaining sets for cooperative games. International Journal of Game Theory, 7, 183–199. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Schofield, N. J. (1985). Social choice and democracy. Heidelberg: Springer. Google Scholar
  28. Schofield, N. J. (1993a). Party competition in a spatial model of coalition formation. In W. A. Barnett, M. J. Hinich, & N. J. Schofield (Eds.), Political economy: institutions, competition, and representation (pp. 135–174). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Google Scholar
  29. Schofield, N. J. (1993b). Political competition and multiparty coalition governments. European Journal of Political Research, 23, 1–33. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Schofield, N. J., & Sened, I. (2006). Multiparty democracy. Elections and legislative politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Google Scholar
  31. Sened, I. (1996). A model of coalition formation: theory and evidence. The Journal of Politics, 58, 350–372. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Tsebelis, G. (1995). Decision making in political systems: veto players in presidentialism, parliamentarism, multicameralism and multipartyism. British Journal of Political Science, 25, 289–325. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Westholm, A. (1997). Distance versus direction: the illusory defeat of proximity theory. American Political Science Review, 91, 865–883. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Westholm, A. (2001). On the return of epicycles: some crossroads in spatial modelling revisited. The Journal of Politics, 63, 436–481. CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2009

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Kiel UniversityKielGermany
  2. 2.Konstanz UniversityKonstanzGermany

Personalised recommendations