Advertisement

Public Choice

, Volume 133, Issue 3–4, pp 377–391 | Cite as

Determinants of interest group formation

  • Dennis Coates
  • Jac C. Heckelman
  • Bonnie WilsonEmail author
Article

Abstract

It is widely recognized that interest groups affect both microeconomic and macroeconomic outcomes. However, few researchers have attempted to discern empirically the factors that contribute to interest group activity. This paper provides a test of several theories of group formation in a panel setting. A nation’s stability, socioeconomic development, political system, size, and diversity all appear to contribute to interest group formation, as predicted by theory.

Keywords

Interest groups Formation 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Alesina, A., Devleeschauwer, A., Easterly, W., & Kurlat, S. (2003). Fractionalization. Journal of Economic Growth, 8, 155–194. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Bischoff, I. (2003). Determinants of the increase in the number of interest groups in western democracies: theoretical considerations and evidence from 21 OECD countries. Public Choice, 114, 197–218. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Black, C. E. (1966). The dynamics of modernization: a study in comparative history. New York: Harper and Row. Google Scholar
  4. Chesher, A., & Jewitt, I. (1987). The bias of a heteroskedasticity consistent covariance matrix estimator. Econometrica, 55, 1217–1222. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Coates, D., & Heckelman, J. (2003). Absolute and relative effects of interest groups on the economy. In J. C. Heckelman & D. Coates (Eds.), Collective choice: essays in honor of Mancur Olson. Berlin: Springer. Google Scholar
  6. Cribari-Neto, F., & Zarkos, S. (1999). Bootstrap methods for heteroskedastic regression models: evidence on estimation and testing. Econometric Reviews, 18, 211–228. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Cribari-Neto, F., & Zarkos, S. (2001). Heteroskedasticity-consistent covariance matrix estimation: White’s estimator and the bootstrap. Journal of Statistical Computation and Simulation, 68, 391–411. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Cribari-Neto, F., Ferrari, S., & Oliveira, W. (2005). Numerical evaluation of tests based on different heteroskedasticity-consistent covariance matrix estimators. Journal of Statistical Computation and Simulation, 75, 611–628. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Greene, W. (1993). Econometric analysis (2nd ed.). New York: Macmillan. Google Scholar
  10. Heckelman, J. C. (2000). Consistent estimates of the impact of special interest groups on economic growth. Public Choice, 104, 319–327. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Heckelman, J. C. (2007). Explaining the rain: The rise and decline of nations after 25 years. Southern Economic Journal, 74(1), 18–33. Google Scholar
  12. James, P. (2003). Developing the Canadian government’s bargaining position on the constitution, June–July 1980: an application of Olson’s argument from “The rise and decline of nations”. In J. C. Heckelman & D. Coates (Eds.), Collective choice: essays in honor of Mancur Olson. Berlin: Springer. Google Scholar
  13. Kang, S., & Meernik, J. (2005). Civil war destruction and the prospects for economic growth. Journal of Politics, 67, 88–109. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Kennelly, B., & Murrell, P. (1991). Industry characteristics and interest group formation: an empirical study. Public Choice, 70, 21–40. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Lacina, B., & Gleditsch, N. P. (2005). Monitoring trends in global combat: a new dataset of battle deaths. European Journal of Population, 21, 145–166. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. MacKinnon, J., & White, H. (1985). Some heteroskedasticity-consistent covariance matrix estimators with improved finite-sample properties. Journal of Econometrics, 29, 305–325. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. McCallum, J., & Blais, A. (1984). Government, special interest groups, and growth. Public Choice, 54, 3–18. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Murrell, P. (1984). An examination of the factors affecting the formation of interest groups in OECD countries. Public Choice, 43, 151–171. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Google Scholar
  20. Olson, M. (1982). The rise and decline of nations: the political economy of growth, stagflation, and social rigidities. New Haven: Yale University Press. Google Scholar
  21. Olson, M. (1983). The south will fall again: the south as leader and laggard in economic growth. Southern Economic Journal, 49, 917–932. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Salisbury, R. H. (1975). Interest groups. In F. I. Greenstein, N. W. Polsby (Eds.), Nongovernmental politics. Reading: Addison-Wesley. Google Scholar
  23. Shughart, W., Tollison, R., & Yan, Z. (2003). Rent seeking into the income distribution. Kyklos, 56, 441–456. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Small, M., & Singer, J. D. (1982). Resort to arms: international and civil wars, 1916–1980. Beverly Hills: Sage. Google Scholar
  25. Tang, E. W. Y., & Hedley, A. (1998). Distributional coalitions, state strength, and economic growth: toward a comprehensive theory of economic development. Public Choice, 96, 295–323. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Weede, E. (1984). Democracy, creeping socialism, and ideological socialism in rent-seeking societies. Public Choice, 44, 349–366. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Zils, M., & Verrel, B. (Eds.). (1973, 1985, 1995, 1999, 2002). World guide to trade associations. München: K.G. Saur. Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, BV 2007

Authors and Affiliations

  • Dennis Coates
    • 1
  • Jac C. Heckelman
    • 2
  • Bonnie Wilson
    • 3
    Email author
  1. 1.Department of EconomicsUniversity of Maryland Baltimore CountyBaltimoreUSA
  2. 2.Department of EconomicsWake Forest UniversityWinston SalemUSA
  3. 3.Department of EconomicsSaint Louis UniversitySaint LouisUSA

Personalised recommendations