Public Choice

, Volume 132, Issue 1–2, pp 191–208 | Cite as

Strategic ratification

Original Article

Abstract

Previous models of ratifier effects have relied on restrictive assumptions regarding the dimensionality of the choice space and the preferences and rationality of actors. These assumptions can lead to an underestimation of the importance of ratifiers and a mischaracterization of their role. A model presented here responds to these concerns and finds that when ratifiers are strategic, ratification requirements consistently aid negotiators in settings where previous models find no effects. Furthermore, new relations between the types of ratifier and the strength of their influence are identified. Negotiators benefit from in-group homogeneity on dimensions along which negotiators agree and from internal dissension on dimensions along which negotiators disagree.

Ratification International negotiation Bargaining 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Banks, J., & Duggan, J. (2000). A bargaining model of collective choice. American Political Science Review, 94, 73–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Butler, C.K. (2004). Modeling compromise at the international table. Conflict Management and Peace Science, 21, 159–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Dai, X. (2002). Political regimes and international trade: The democratic difference revisited. American Political Science Review, 96, 159–65.Google Scholar
  4. Evans, P., Jacobson, H., & Putnam, R. (1993). Double-edged diplomacy: International bargaining and domestic politics. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
  5. Fudenberg, D., & Tirole, J. (1995). Game theory. Cambridge: MIT University Press.Google Scholar
  6. Haller, H., & Holden, S. (1997). Ratification requirement and bargaining power. International Economic Review, 38, 825–851.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Hammond, T.H., & Prins, B. (1999, September). The impact of domestic institutions on international negotiations: A taxonomy of results from a complete-information spatial model. Paper presented at the 95th Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Atlanta.Google Scholar
  8. Hayes, D., & Smith, A. (1997). The shadow of the polls: Electoral effects on international agreements. International Interactions, 23, 79–108.Google Scholar
  9. Hug, S., & König, T. (2002). In view of ratification: Governmental preferences and domestic constraints at the Amsterdam Intergovernmental Conference. International Organization, 56, 447–476.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Hug, S. (September, 2004). Models of multilateral negotiations and ratification. Paper presented at the 2004 meetings of the American Political Science Association, Chicago.Google Scholar
  11. Iida, K. (1993). When and how do domestic constraints matter? Two level games with uncertainty. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 34, 403–426.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Iida, K. (1996). Involuntary defection in two level games. Public Choice, 89, 283–303.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Mansfield, E.D., Milner, H.V., & Rosendorff, B.P. (2000). Free to trade: Democracies, autocracies and international trade. American Political Science Review, 94, 305–322.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Mansfield, E.D., Milner, H.V., & Rosendorff, B.P. (2002). Replication, realism and robustness: Analyzing political regimes and international trade. American Political Science Review, 96, 167–69.Google Scholar
  15. Milner, H.V. (1997). Interests, institutions, and information: Domestic politics and international relations. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  16. Milner, H.V., & Rosendorff, B.P. (1997). Democratic politics and international trade negotiations: Elections and divided government as constraints on trade liberalization. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 41, 117–146.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Mo, J. (1994). The logic of two level games with endogenous domestic coalitions. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 38, 402–422.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Mo, J. (1995). Domestic institutions and international bargaining: The role of agent veto in two-level games. American Political Science Review, 89, 914–924.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Osborne, M.J., & Rubinstein, A. (1994). A course in game theory. Cambridge: MIT University Press.Google Scholar
  20. Pahre, R. (1997). Endogenous domestic institutions in two-level games and parliamentary oversight of the European Union. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 41, 147–174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Putnam, R. (1988). Diplomacy and domestic politics: The logic of two-level games. International Organization, 42, 427–460.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Rubinstein, A. (1982). Perfect equilibrium in a bargaining model. Econometrica, 50, 97–109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Schelling, T.C. (1960). The strategy of conflict. Cambridge, Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  24. Ståhl, I. (1972). Bargaining theory. Mimeo. Stockholm School of Economics, Stockholm.Google Scholar
  25. Tarar, A. (2001). International bargaining with two-sided domestic constraints. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 45, 320–340.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Tarar, A. (2004). Bargaining power, the schelling conjecture, and fast-track trade negotiating authority. Mimeo. Department of Political Science, Texas A&M University.Google Scholar
  27. Tarar, A. (2005). Constituencies and preferences in international bargaining. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 49, 383–407.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2007

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Columbia UniversityNew YorkUSA

Personalised recommendations