Advertisement

Policy Sciences

, Volume 42, Issue 3, pp 243–273 | Cite as

Signaling virtue: voluntary accountability programs among nonprofit organizations

  • Mary Kay GugertyEmail author
Article

Abstract

This article examines the structure of nonprofit voluntary accountability and standard-setting programs, arguing that these programs can be understood as collective action institutions designed to address information asymmetries between nonprofits and their stakeholders. Club theory and the economics of certification suggest that such programs have the potential to provide a signal of quality by setting high standards and fees and rigorously verifying compliance. Such mechanisms can signal quality because higher participation costs may allow only high-quality organizations to join. The article examines the implications of signaling theory using an original dataset on the structure of 32 nonprofit accountability programs across the globe. While many programs set high standards for compliance, the key distinction between strong and weak programs is the use of disclosure or verification mechanisms to enforce compliance. Contrary to theoretical expectations, compliance standards and verification do not appear to be substitutes in creating stronger voluntary programs.

Keywords

Nonprofit accountability Collective action Voluntary programs Voluntary clubs Self-regulation Certification 

Notes

Acknowledgments

Thanks to Travis Reynolds for excellent research assistance and to Aseem Prakash, Matt Potoski, Jodi Sandfort, and Stephen B. Page for valuable comments on earlier versions of this article. In addition, I thank two anonymous referees for their very helpful feedback. All errors remain my own.

References

  1. Akerlof, G. A. (1970). The market for ‘lemons’: Quality uncertainty and the market mechanism. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84(3), 488–500.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Arumi, A. M., Wooden R., & Johnson, J. (2005). The charitable impulse. Public Agenda.Google Scholar
  3. Bartley, T. (2007). Institutional emergence in an era of globalization. The rise of transnational private regulation of labor and environmental conditions. American Journal of Sociology, 13(2), 297–351.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Bekkers, R. (2003). Trust, accreditation and philanthropy in the Netherlands. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 32(4), 596–615.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Ben-Nur, A., & Gui, B. (2003). The theory of nonprofit organizations revisited. In H. Anheier & A. Ben-Nur (Eds.), The study of nonprofit enterprise: Theories and approaches. New York: Kluwer Academic Publishers.Google Scholar
  6. Bornstein, L. (2003). Management standards and development practice in the South African aid chain. Public Administration and Development, 23, 393–404.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Bothwell, R. O. (2001). Trends in self-regulation and transparency of nonprofit organizations in the U.S. The International Journal of Not-for-Profit Law, 4(1).Google Scholar
  8. Bowman, W. (2008). Trends and patterns in accreditation clubs. Paper Presented at the Nonprofit Accountability Clubs Workshop, University of Washington.Google Scholar
  9. Bradley, B., Jansen, P., & Silverman, L. (2003). The nonprofit sector’s $100 billion opportunity. Harvard Business Review, May 1.Google Scholar
  10. Brody, E. (2002). Accountability and public trust. In L. Salamon (Ed.), The state of nonprofit America. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution and the Aspen Institute.Google Scholar
  11. Buchanan, J. M. (1965). An economic theory of clubs. Economica, 32, 1–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Christensen, J. (2004). Asking the do-gooders to prove they do good. The New York Times, January 3, 2004.Google Scholar
  13. Coglianese, C., & Nash, J. (2009). Applying club theory to government-sponsored voluntary programs. In A. M. Potoski & A. Prakash (Eds.), Voluntary programs: A club theory approach. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  14. Cooley, A., & Ron, J. (2002). The NGO scramble: Organizational insecurity and the political economy of transnational action. International Security, 27(1), 5–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (1996). The theory of externalities, public goods and club goods. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  16. Dale, H. (2005). Study on models of self-regulation in the nonprofit sector. National Center on Philanthropy and the Law and Independent Sector. Retrieved April 27, 2009, from http://www3.law.nyu.edu/ncpl/library/Self-Regulation.pdf.
  17. Darnall, N., & Carmin, J. (2005). Greener and cleaner? The signaling accuracy of U.S. voluntary environmental programs. Policy Sciences, 38(7), 1–90.Google Scholar
  18. Darnall, N., & Sides, S. (2008). Assessing the performance of voluntary environmental programs: Does certification matter? Policy Studies Journal, 36(1), 95–117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. deLeon, P., & Rivera, J. (2007). Voluntary environmental programs: A symposium. Policy Studies Journal, 35(4), 685–688.Google Scholar
  20. Delmas, M., & Keller, A. (2005). Free riding in voluntary environmental programs: The case of the U.S. EPA WasteWise program. Policy Sciences, 38(7), 91–106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. DeMarzo, P., Fishman, M., & Hagerty, K. (2005). Self-regulation and government oversight. Review of Economic Studies, 72, 687–706.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. DiMaggio, P., & Powell, W. (Eds.). (1991). The new institutionalism in organizational analysis. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  23. Ebrahim, A. (2005). NGOs and organizational change: Discourse, reporting and learning. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  24. Edelman Trust. (2007). Edelman trust barometer 2007. www.edelman.com/trust/2007/trust_final_1_31.pdf.
  25. Fox, M., & Brown, L. D. (1998). The struggle for accountability: The World Bank, NGOs, and grassroots movements. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  26. Fremont-Smith, M., & Kosaras, A. (2003). Wrongdoing by officers and directors of charities: A survey of press reports, 1995-2002. Working paper number 20. Cambridge: Hauser Center for Nonprofit Organizations, Harvard University.Google Scholar
  27. Gibbelman, M., & Gelman, S. (2004). A loss of credibility: Patterns of wrongdoing among nonprofit organizations. VOLUNTAS: International Journal of Voluntary and Nonprofit Organizations, 15(4), 355–381.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Greenlee, J., Fischer, M., Gordon, T., & Keating, E. (2007). An investigation of fraud in nonprofit organizations: Occurrences and deterrents. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 36(4), 676–694.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Gugerty, M. K. (2008). The effectiveness of NGO self-regulation: Theory and evidence from Africa. Public Administration and Development, 28, 105–118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Gunningham, N., & Rees, N. (1997). Industry self-regulation: An institutionalist perspective. Law and Policy, 4, 363–414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Hansmann, H. B. (1980). The role of nonprofit enterprise. Yale Law Review, 89, 835–898.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Hansman, H. B. (2003). The role of trust in nonprofit enterprise. In H. Anheier & A. Ben-Nur (Eds.), The study of nonprofit enterprise: Theories and approaches. New York: Kluwer Academic Publishers.Google Scholar
  33. Harbaugh, R., Maxwell, J. W., &, Rousillon, B. (2008). Uncertain standards. Resource document. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=948538.
  34. Hopgood, S. (2005). Professionalization and bureaucratization of humanitarian action. Paper Prepared for the Social Sciences Research Council Initiative, The Transformation of Humanitarian Action, March 23, 2005.Google Scholar
  35. Independent Sector. (2005). Strengthening transparency governance accountability of charitable organizations: A final report to congress and the nonprofit sector. Resource document. Independent Sector. Retrieved November 20, 2008, from http://info.ethicspoint.com/files/PDF/resources/Panel_Final_Report.pdf.
  36. Independent Sector. (2007). Principles for good governance and ethical practice: A guide for charities and foundations. Resource document. Panel on the Nonprofit Sector, Independent Sector. Retrieved October 1, 2007, from http://www.nonprofitpanel.org/report/principles/Principles_Guide.pdf.
  37. Johnson, E., & Prakash, A. (2007). NGO research program: A collective action perspective. Policy Sciences, 40(3), 221–240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Keck, M., & Sikkink, K. (1998). Activists beyond borders: Advocacy networks in international politics. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
  39. King, A., & Lenox, M. (2000). Industry self-regulation without sanctions: The chemical industry’s responsible care program. Academy of Management Journal, 43(4), 698–716.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Kleiner, M. (2006). Licensing occupations: Ensuring quality or restricting competition?. Kalamazoo, MI: W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research.Google Scholar
  41. Kovach, H., Nelligan, C., & Burall, S. (2003). Power without accountability. One World Trust, Global Accountability Report.Google Scholar
  42. Kreps, D. (1990). Corporate culture and economic theory. In K. Shepsle & J. Alt (Eds.), Perspectives on positive political economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  43. Lenox, M. J., & Nash, J. (2003). Industry self-regulation and adverse selection: A comparison across four trade association programs. Business Strategy and the Environment, 12, 343–356.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Light, P. C. (2004). Sustaining nonprofit performance. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.Google Scholar
  45. Lizzeri, A. (1999). Information revelation and certification intermediaries. RAND Journal of Economics, 30(2), 214–231.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  46. Lloyd, R. (2005). The role of NGO self-regulation in increasing stakeholder accountability. One World Trust.Google Scholar
  47. Lloyd, R., & de las Casas, L. (2005). NGO self-regulation: enforcing and balancing accountability. Alliance Extra.Google Scholar
  48. Maxfield, S., & Schneider, B. (1997). Business and the state in developing countries. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
  49. McDougle, L. M., Deitrick, L., Libby, P., & Donmoyer, R. (2008). The appreciated sector: Public confidence in San Diego county nonprofit organizations. Caser Family Center for Nonprofit Research, University of San Diego.Google Scholar
  50. Moore, M., Brown, L. D., & Honan, J. (2003). Strengthening the accountability of international nongovernmental organizations: An analytic framework and implementation guidelines. Cambridge: Hauser Center for Nonprofit Organizations.Google Scholar
  51. Myslivecek, J. (2008). Adverse selection in imperfect competition (working paper). Prague: CERGE-EI, Charles University.Google Scholar
  52. Naidoo, K. (2004). The end of blind faith? Civil society and the challenges of accountability, transparency and legitimacy. AccountAbility Forum, Issue 2, 14–15.Google Scholar
  53. Nunez, J. (2007). Can self-regulation work? A story of corruption, impunity and cover-up. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 31, 206–233.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. O’Neill, M. (2009). Public confidence in charitable nonprofits. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 38(2), 237–269.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  55. Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  56. Ortmann, A., & Schlesinger, M. (2003). Trust, repute and the role of nonprofit enterprise. In H. Anheier & A. Ben-Nur (Eds.), The study of nonprofit enterprise: Theories and approaches. New York: Kluwer Academic Publishers.Google Scholar
  57. Ortmann, A., & Svitkova, K. (2007). Certification as a viable quality assurance mechanism in transition economies: Evidence, theory and open questions. Prague: Prague Economic Papers.Google Scholar
  58. Ostrower, F., & Stone, M. (2006). Governance: Research trends, gaps and future prospects. In W. Powell & R. Steinberg (Eds.), The nonprofit sector research handbook. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  59. Platteau, J.-P., & Gaspart, F. (2003). Disciplining local leaders in community-based development. Working paper. CRED, University of Namur.Google Scholar
  60. Potoski, M., & Prakash, A. (Eds.). (2009). Voluntary programs: A club theory approach. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  61. Prakash, A., & Potoski, M. (2006). The voluntary environmentalists. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  62. Prakash, A., & Potoski, M. (2007). Collective action through voluntary environmental programs: A club theory perspective. Policy Studies Journal, 35(4), 773–792.Google Scholar
  63. Rivera, J., & de Leon, P. (2004). Is greener whiter? Voluntary environmental performance of western ski areas. Policy Studies Journal, 32(3), 417–438.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  64. Rivera, J., de Leon, P., & Koerber, C. (2006). Is greener whiter yet? The sustainable slopes program after five years. Policy Studies Journal, 34(2), 195–222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  65. Rose-Ackerman, S. (1996). Altruism, nonprofits, and economic theory. Journal of Economic Literature, 34, 701–728.Google Scholar
  66. Salamon, L. (2002). The resilient sector: The state of nonprofit America. In L. Salamon (Ed.), The state of nonprofit America. Washington, DC: Brookings Institute Press.Google Scholar
  67. Schlesinger, M., Mitchell, S., & Gray, B. H. (2004). Restoring public legitimacy to the nonprofit sector: A survey experiment using descriptions of nonprofit ownership. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 33(4), 673–710.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  68. Scott, W. R. (1995). Institutions and organizations. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
  69. Shaked, A., & Sutton, J. (1981). The self-regulating profession. Review of Economic Studies, 48(2), 217–234.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  70. Sidel, M. (2003). Trends in nonprofit self-regulation in the Asia Pacific region. Paper Presented to the Asia Pacific Philanthropy Consortium.Google Scholar
  71. Sidel, M. (2004). More secure, less free?: Antiterrorism policy and civil liberties after 9/11. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
  72. Spence, M. (1973). Job market signaling. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 88, 355–374.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  73. Steinberg, R. (2006). Economic theories of nonprofit organizations. In J. Powell & R. Steinberg (Eds.), The nonprofit sector research handbook. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  74. Steinberg, R., & Gray, B. (1993). The role of nonprofit enterprise in 1993: Hansmann revisited. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 22(4), 297–316.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  75. Strausz, R. (2005). Honest certification and the threat of capture. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 23, 45–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  76. Svitkova, K. (2007). Prompted to be good: The impact of certification on the quality of charities. CERGE-EI working paper 320. Prague: Charles University.Google Scholar
  77. Terlaak, A., & King, A. (2006). The effect of certification with the ISO 9000 quality management standard: A signaling approach. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 60, 579–602.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  78. The Economist. (2003). Who guards the guardians? Resource document. The Economist. Retrieved November 20, 2008, from http://www.economist.com/science/displaystory.cfm?story_id=2077493.
  79. Tiebout, C. M. (1956). A pure theory of local public expenditures. Journal of Political Economy, 64, 416–424.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  80. Tirole, J. (1989). The theory of industrial organization. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  81. Toffel, M. W. (2006). Resolving information asymmetries in markets: The role of certified management programs. Working paper 07-023. Cambridge: Harvard Business School.Google Scholar
  82. Wapner, P. (2002). Defending accountability in NGOs. Chicago Journal of International Law, 3(1), 197–205.Google Scholar
  83. Weisbrod, B. (1988). The nonprofit economy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  84. Weisbrod, B. (1998). Institutional form and organizational behavior. In W. Powell & E. Clemens (Eds.), Private action and the public good. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  85. Wiseman, J. 1957. The theory of public utility pricing: An empty box. Oxford Economic Papers.Google Scholar
  86. Young, D. (1998). Commercialism in nonprofit social service associations: Its character, significance and rationale. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 17(2), 278–297.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  87. Zadek, S. (2003). In defence of nonprofit accountability. Ethical Corporation Magazine, September, 34–36.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC. 2009

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Evans School of Public AffairsUniversity of WashingtonSeattleUSA

Personalised recommendations