Advertisement

Journal of Economic Growth

, Volume 15, Issue 3, pp 177–204 | Cite as

The trade-off between fertility and education: evidence from before the demographic transition

  • Sascha O. Becker
  • Francesco Cinnirella
  • Ludger Woessmann
Article

Abstract

The trade-off between child quantity and quality is a crucial ingredient of unified growth models that explain the transition from Malthusian stagnation to modern growth. We present first evidence that such a trade-off indeed existed already in the nineteenth century, exploiting a unique census-based dataset of 334 Prussian counties in 1849. Furthermore, we find that causation between fertility and education runs both ways, based on separate instrumental-variable models that instrument fertility by sex ratios and education by landownership inequality and distance to Wittenberg. Education in 1849 also predicts the fertility transition in 1880–1905.

Keywords

Schooling Fertility transition Unified growth theory Nineteenth-century Prussia 

JEL Classification

N33 O15 I20 J13 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Abramitzky R., Delavande A., Vasconcelos L. (2010) Marrying up: The role of sex ratio in assortative matching. Stanford University, MimeoGoogle Scholar
  2. Angrist J. D. (2002) How do sex ratios affect marriage and labor markets? Evidence from America’s second generation. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117(3): 997–1038CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Angrist, J. D., Lavy, V., & Schlosser, A. (2005). New evidence on the causal link between the quantity and quality of children. NBER Working Paper 11835. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
  4. Becker G. S. (1960) An economic analysis of fertility. In: Becker G. S. (ed) Demographic and economic change in developed countries. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, pp 209–240Google Scholar
  5. Becker G. S., Lewis H. G. (1973) On the interaction between the quantity and quality of children. Journal of Political Economy 81(2, part 2): S279–S288CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Becker G. S., Tomes N. (1976) Child endowments and the quantity and quality of children. Journal of Political Economy 84(4, part 2): S143–S162CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Becker S. O., Woessmann L. (2008) Luther and the girls: Religious denomination and the female education gap in 19th century Prussia. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 110(4): 777–805CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Becker S. O., Woessmann L. (2009) Was Weber Wrong? A human capital theory of Protestant economic history. Quarterly Journal of Economics 124(2): 531–596CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Becker S. O., Woessmann L. (2010) The effect of Protestantism on education before the industrialization: Evidence from 1816 Prussia. Economics Letters 107(2): 224–228CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Bengtsson T., Dribe M. (2006) Deliberate control in a natural fertility population: Southern Sweden, 1766–1864. Demography 43(4): 727–746CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Berger H., Spoerer M. (2001) Economic crisis and the European revolutions of 1848. Journal of Economic History 61(2): 293–326CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Black S. E., Devereux P. J., Salvanes K. G. (2005) The more the Merrier? The effect of family size and birth order on children’s education. Quarterly Journal of Economics 120(2): 669–700CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Bleakley H., Lange F. (2009) Chronic disease burden and the interaction of education, fertility, and growth. Review of Economics and Statistics 91(1): 52–65CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Breierova, L., & Duflo, E. (2004). The impact of education on fertility and child mortality: Do fathers really matter less than mothers? NBER Working Paper 10513. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
  15. Brown J. C., Guinnane T. W. (2002) Fertility transition in a rural, Catholic population: Bavaria, 1880–1910. Population Studies 56(1): 35–49CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Brown J. C., Guinnane T. W. (2007) Regions and time in the European fertility transition: Problems in the Princeton project’s statistical methodology. Economic History Review 60(3): 574–595CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Cervellati M., Sunde U. (2005) Human capital formation, life expectancy, and the process of development. American Economic Review 95(5): 1653–1672CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Cervellati, M., & Sunde, U. (2009). Life Expectancy and economic growth: The role of the demographic transition. IZA Discussion Paper 4160. Bonn: Institute for the Study of Labor.Google Scholar
  19. Clark G. (2007) A Farewell to Alms: A brief economic history of the world. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJGoogle Scholar
  20. Coale A. J., Watkins S. C. (1986) The decline of fertility in Europe. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJGoogle Scholar
  21. Cubberley E. P. (1920) The history of education. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UKGoogle Scholar
  22. Doepke M. (2004) Accounting for fertility decline during the transition to growth. Journal of Economic Growth 9(3): 347–383CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Doepke M. (2005) Child mortality and fertility decline: Does the Barro-Becker model fit the facts?. Journal of Population Economics 18(2): 337–366CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Flora, P., Kraus, F., Pfenning, W. (eds) (1983) State, economy and society in Western Europe 1815–1975. St. James Press, Chicago, ILGoogle Scholar
  25. Galloway P. R., Hammel E. A., Lee R. D. (1994) Fertility decline in Prussia, 1875–1910: A pooled cross-section time series analysis. Population Studies 48(1): 135–158CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Galloway P. R., Lee R. D., Hammel E. A. (1998) Urban versus rural fertility decline in the cities and rural districts of Prussia, 1875 to 1910. European Journal of Population 14(3): 209–264CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Galor O. (2005) From stagnation to growth: Unified growth theory. In: Aghion P., Durlauf S. N. (eds) Handbook of economic growth. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 171–293CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Galor O. (2005) The demographic transition and the emergence of sustained economic growth. Journal of the European Economic Association 3(2-3): 494–504CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Galor O. (2010) Unified growth theory. Princeton University Press, Princeton NJ (forthcoming)Google Scholar
  30. Galor O., Moav O. (2002) Natural selection and the origin of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117(4): 1133–1191CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Galor O., Moav O. (2006) Das Human-Kapital: A theory of the demise of the class structure. Review of Economic Studies 73(1): 85–117CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Galor O., Moav O., Vollrath D. (2009) Inequality in land ownership, the emergence of human capital promoting institutions, and the great divergence. Review of Economic Studies 76(1): 143–179CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Galor O., Weil D. N. (1999) From Malthusian stagnation to modern growth. American Economic Review 89(2): 150–154CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Galor O., Weil D. N. (2000) Population, technology, and growth: From Malthusian stagnation to the demographic transition and beyond. American Economic Review 90(4): 806–828CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Goldin C., Katz L. F. (2008) The race between education and technology. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
  36. Guinnane T. W. (2008) The historical fertility transition and theories of long-run growth: A guide for economists. Yale University, MimeoGoogle Scholar
  37. Guinnane T. W., Okun B. S., Trussell J. (1994) What do we know about the timing of fertility transitions in Europe?. Demography 31(1): 1–20CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Hajnal J. (1965) European marriage patterns in perspective. In: Glass D. V., Eversley D. E. C. (eds) Population in history: Essays in historical demography. Edward Arnold, London, pp 101–143Google Scholar
  39. Hansen G. D., Prescott E. C. (2002) Malthus to solow. American Economic Review 92(4): 1205–1217CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Hanushek E. A. (1992) The trade-off between child quantity and quality. Journal of Political Economy 100(1): 84–117CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Jayachandran S., Lleras-Muney A. (2009) Life expectancy and human capital investments: Evidence from maternal mortality declines. Quarterly Journal of Economics 124(1): 349–397CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Kalemli-Ozcan S. (2003) A stochastic model of mortality, fertility, and human capital investment. Journal of Development Economics 70: 103–118CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Knodel J. E. (1974) The decline of fertility in Germany, 1871–1939. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJGoogle Scholar
  44. Knodel J. E. (1988) Demographic behavior in the past: A study of fourteen German village populations in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Lucas R. E. (2002) Lectures on economic growth. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
  46. Moav O. (2005) Cheap children and the persistence of poverty. Economic Journal 115(500): 88–110CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Qian, N. (2009). Quantity-quality and the one child policy: The only-child disadvantage in school enrollment in rural China. NBER Working Paper 14973. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
  48. Rosenzweig M. R., Wolpin K. I. (1980) Testing the quantity-quality fertility model: The use of twins as a natural experiment. Econometrica 48(1): 227–240CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Rosenzweig M. R., Zhang J. (2009) Do population control policies induce more human capital investment? Twins, birthweight, and China’s ‘One Child’ policy. Review of Economic Studies 76(3): 1149–1174CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. Schultz T. P. (2008) Population policies, fertility, women’s human capital, and child quality. In: Schultz T. P., John S. (eds) Handbook of development economics. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 3249–3303Google Scholar
  51. Soares R. R. (2005) Mortality reductions, educational attainment, and fertility choice. American Economic Review 95(3): 580–601CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  52. Strulik H., Weisdorf J. (2008) Population, food, and knowledge: A simple unified growth theory. Journal of Economic Growth 13(3): 195–216CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  53. Willis R. J. (1973) A new approach to the economic theory of fertility behavior. Journal of Political Economy 81(2, part 2): S14–S64CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Wooldridge J. M. (2002) Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. MIT Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2010

Authors and Affiliations

  • Sascha O. Becker
    • 1
  • Francesco Cinnirella
    • 2
  • Ludger Woessmann
    • 2
    • 3
  1. 1.Department of EconomicsUniversity of WarwickCoventryUK
  2. 2.Ifo Institute for Economic ResearchMunichGermany
  3. 3.Department of EconomicsUniversity of MunichMunichGermany

Personalised recommendations