Advertisement

Journal of Economic Growth

, Volume 13, Issue 2, pp 125–144 | Cite as

Technological progress and regress in pre-industrial times

  • Shekhar Aiyar
  • Carl-Johan Dalgaard
  • Omer Moav
Article

Abstract

This paper offers micro-foundations for the dynamic relationship between technology and population in the pre-industrial world, accounting for both technological progress and the hitherto neglected but common phenomenon of technological regress. A positive feedback between population and the adoption of new techniques that increase the division of labor explains technological progress. A transient shock to productivity or population induces the neglect of some techniques rendered temporarily unprofitable, which are therefore not transmitted to the next generation. Productivity remains constrained by the smaller stock of knowledge and technology has thereby regressed. A slow process of rediscovery is required for the economy to reach its previous level of technological sophistication and population size. The model is employed to analyze specific historical examples of technological regress.

Inventions don’t just get adopted once and forever; they have to be constantly practised and transmitted, or useful techniques may be forgotten.

Jared Diamond, Ten Thousand Years of Solitude, 1993.

Keywords

Technological regress Technological progress Malthusian stagnation Division of labor 

JEL Classifications

O10 O33 O40 J11 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Aghion P., Howitt P. (1992) A model of rowth through creative destruction. Econometrica 60: 323–51CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Arrow K. (1962) The economic implications of learning-by-doing. Review of Economic Studies 29: 155–73CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Baker, M., (2007). A structural model of the neolithic revolution. Working Paper (Hunter College).Google Scholar
  4. Biraben J.N. (1979) Essai sur l’evolution du nombre des hommes. Population 34: 13–25CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Boserup E. (1965) The conditions of agricultural growth. Adeline Publishing Company, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  6. Botticini, M., & Siow, A. (2005). The value of sons in pre-modern economies: A view from the marriage Market. Boston University.Google Scholar
  7. Brander J., Taylor S. (1997) The simple economics of Easter Island: A Ricardo-Malthus model of renewable resource use. American Economic Review 88: 119–138Google Scholar
  8. Cervellati M., Sunde U. (2005) Human capital formation, life expectancy and the process of development. American Economic Review 95: 1653–1672CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Ciccone A., Hall R. (1996) Productivity and the density of economic activity. American Economic Review 86: 54–70Google Scholar
  10. Clark, G., & Hamilton, G. (2004). Was pre-industrial society malthusian? Tests from England and New France. Working Paper, UC Davis.Google Scholar
  11. Comin, D., Easterly, W., & Gong, E. (2006). Was the wealth of nations determined in 1000 B.C.? Working paper, New York University.Google Scholar
  12. Cottrell L. (1964) The concise encyclopedia of archaeology (2nd ed). Hawthorn Books, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  13. de la Croix D., Doepke M. (2003) Inequality and growth: Why differential fertility matters. American Economic Review 93: 1091–113CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Delaine, J. (1997). The Baths of Caracalla in Rome: A study in the design, construction and economics of large-scale building projects in imperial Rome. Journal of Roman Archeology Supplement, 25 (Portsmouth R.I. 1997).Google Scholar
  15. Diamond, J. (1993). Ten thousand years of solitude. Discover Magazine.Google Scholar
  16. Diamond, J. (1995). Easter Island’s End. Discover Magazine.Google Scholar
  17. Diamond J. (1997) Guns, germs and steel. W.W. Norton, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  18. Diamond J. (2004) Collapse—how societies choose to fail or succeed. Penguin Books, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  19. Doepke, M. (2002). Accounting for fertility decline during the transition to growth. UCLA working paper.Google Scholar
  20. Eaton J., Kortum S. (1999) International technology diffusion: Theory and measurement. International Economic Review. 40: 537–70CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Finley M.I. (1965) Technical innovation and economic progress in the ancient world. Economic History Review 18: 29–45CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Fishman A., Simhon A. (2002) The division of labor, inequality and growth. Journal of Economic Growth 7: 117–136CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Galor O. (2005) From stagnation to growth: Unified growth theory. In: Aghion P., Durlauf S.(eds) Handbook of economic growth. North Holland, Amsterdam, pp 171–293CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Galor O., Moav O. (2002) Natural selection and the origin of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117: 1133–1191CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Galor O., Weil D. (2000) Population, technology and growth: From malthusian stagnation to the demographic transition and beyond. American Economic Review 90: 806–828CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Goodfriend M., McDermott J. (1995) Early development. American Economic Review 85: 116–33Google Scholar
  27. Grantham G. (1999) Contra Ricardo: On the macroeconomics of pre-industrial economics. European Review of Economic History 2: 199–232Google Scholar
  28. Greene K. (1990) Perspectives on Roman technology. Oxford Journal of Archaeology 22: 209–219CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Greene K. (2000) Technical innovation and economic progress in the Ancient world: M.I. Finley re-considered. Economic History Review 53: 29–59CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Grossman G., Helpman E. (1991) Innovation and growth in the global economy. MIT Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  31. Hansen G., Prescott E. (2002) Malthus to Solow. American Economic Review 92: 1205–1217CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Hazan, M., & Zoabi, H. (2004). Longevity, fertility and economic growth. Mimeo, Hebrew University.Google Scholar
  33. Hoffman, P. (1996). Growth in a traditional society: The French country side 1440–1815. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  34. Hong S., Candelone J.P., Burton C. (1994) Greenland ice evidence of hemispheric lead pollution two millennia ago by Greek and Roman civilization. Science 265: 246–249CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Jones C.I. (2007) Growth and Ideas. In: Aghion P., Durlauf S.(eds) Handbook of economic growth. Amsterdam, North HollandGoogle Scholar
  36. Kelly M. (1997) The dynamics of smithian growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 112: 939–964CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Kelly, M. (2004). Living standards and population growth: Malthus was right. University College Dublin.Google Scholar
  38. King R. (2000) Brunelleschi’s Dome. Penguin Books, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  39. Kortum S. (1997) Research, patenting, and technological change. Econometrica 65: 1389–1419CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Kremer M. (1993) Population growth and technological change: One million B.C. to 1990. Quarterly Journal of Economics 108: 681–716CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Lagerlof N.P. (2003) From Malthus to modern growth: Can epidemics explain the three regimes?. International Economic Review 44: 755–777CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  42. Livi-Bacci M. (1997) A Concise History of World population (2nd. ed). Blackwell, OxfordGoogle Scholar
  43. Lucas, R. E. Jr. (Ed.). (2002). The industrial revolution: Past and future. In Lectures on economic growth. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  44. Mainstone R. (1970) Brunelleschi’s dome of S. Maria del Fiore and some related structures. Transactions of the Newcomen Society 42: 107–126Google Scholar
  45. Mokyr, J. (2002). The gifts of Athena. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  46. Nelson R.R., Phelps E.S. (1966) Investment in humans, technological diffusion, and economic growth. American Economic Review 56: 69–75Google Scholar
  47. Olsson O. (2000) Knowledge as a set in idea space: An epistemological view on growth. Journal of Economic Growth 5: 253–275CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Phelps N. (1966) Models of technological progress and the golden rule of research. Review of Economic Studies 33: 133–145CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Romer P. (1990) Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy 98: S71–S102CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  50. Simon J., Sullivan R.J. (1989) Population size, knowledge stock, and other determinants of agricultural publication and pateting: England, 1541–1850. Explorations in Economic History 26: 21–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Sorokin P.A. (1962) Social and Cultural Dynamics (Vol II) 2nd edn. The Bedminster Press, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  52. Temin P. (2006) The economy of the early Roman empire.Journal of Economic Perspectives 20: 133–151Google Scholar
  53. Tilburg J.A.V., Ralston T. (2005) Megaliths and Mariners: Experimental archaeology on Easter Island. In: Johnson K.L.(eds) Onward and upward: Essays in Honor of Clement W. Meighan. University Press of America, Lanham, MDGoogle Scholar
  54. Weitzman M. (1998) Recombinant growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 113: 331–360CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  55. Wilson A. (2002) Machines, power and the ancient economy. The Journal of Roman Studies 92: 1–32CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  56. Wilson, A. (2006). The economic impact of technological advances in the Roman construction industry. In E. Lo Cascio (Ed.), Innovazione tecnica e progresso economico nel mondo romano. (Pragmateiai) (pp. 225–236.). Bari, Edipuglia.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2008

Authors and Affiliations

  • Shekhar Aiyar
    • 1
  • Carl-Johan Dalgaard
    • 2
  • Omer Moav
    • 3
    • 4
    • 5
    • 6
  1. 1.International Monetary FundWashingtonUSA
  2. 2.University of CopenhagenCopenhagenDenmark
  3. 3.Hebrew UniversityJerusalamIsreal
  4. 4.Royal Holloway University of LondonEghamUK
  5. 5.Shalem CenterJerusalamIsreal
  6. 6.CEPRLondonUK

Personalised recommendations