Journal of Economic Growth

, Volume 12, Issue 2, pp 77–99 | Cite as

Why does democracy need education?

  • Edward L. Glaeser
  • Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto
  • Andrei Shleifer
Article

Abstract

Across countries, education and democracy are highly correlated. We motivate empirically and then model a causal mechanism explaining this correlation. In our model, schooling teaches people to interact with others and raises the benefits of civic participation, including voting and organizing. In the battle between democracy and dictatorship, democracy has a wide potential base of support but offers weak incentives to its defenders. Dictatorship provides stronger incentives to a narrower base. As education raises the benefits of civic engagement, it raises participation in support of a broad-based regime (democracy) relative to that in support of a narrow-based regime (dictatorship). This increases the likelihood of successful democratic revolutions against dictatorships, and reduces that of successful anti-democratic coups.

Keywords

Democracy Education Political participation 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Acemoglu D., Johnson S., Robinson J., Yared P. (2005). From education to democracy. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 95, 44–49Google Scholar
  2. Almond, G., & Verba, S. (1989, 1st ed. 1963). The civic culture: Political attitudes and democracy in five nations. London: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
  3. Arellano M., Bond S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. The Review of Economic Studies, 58, 277–297CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Barro R. (1997). Determinants of economic growth. Cambridge, MA, MIT PressGoogle Scholar
  5. Barro R. (1999). Determinants of democracy. Journal of Political Economy, 107, 158–183CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Barro R., Lee J.-W. (2001). International data on educational attainment: Updates and implications. Oxford Economic Papers, 53, 541–563CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Blundell R., Bond S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87, 115–143CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Bobba, M., & Coviello, D. (2006). Weak instruments and weak identification in estimating the effects of education on democracy. Economics Letters (forthcoming).Google Scholar
  9. Boix C., Stokes S. (2003), Endogenous democratization. World Politics, 55, 517–549CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Bourguignon F., Verdier T. (2000). Oligarchy, democracy, inequality, and growth. Journal of Development Economics, 62, 285–313CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Bowles S., Gintis H. (1976). Schooling in capitalist America: Educational reform and the contradictions of capitalist life. New York, Basic BooksGoogle Scholar
  12. Brady H., Verba S., Schlozman K.L. (1995). Beyond SES: A resource model of political participation. American Political Science Review, 89, 271–294CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Campante F., Do Q.-A. (2005). Inequality, redistribution, and population. Mimeo, Harvard UniversityGoogle Scholar
  14. Castello-Climent, A. (2006). On the distribution of education and democracy. Working Paper 0602, Institute of International Economics, University of Valencia.Google Scholar
  15. Cooper R., John A. (1988). Coordinating coordination failures in Keynesian models. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 103, 441–465CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Costa D., Kahn M. (2003). Cowards and heroes: Group loyalty in the American civil war. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118, 519–548CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Dee T. (2004). Are there civic returns to education?. Journal of Public Economics, 88, 1697–1720CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. De Long B., Shleifer A. (1993). Princes and merchants: European city growth before the industrial revolution. Journal of Law and Economics, 36, 671–702CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. DiPasquale D., Glaeser E. (1999). Incentive and social capital: Are homeowners better citizens?. Journal of Urban Economics, 45, 354–384CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Driscoll A., Nagel N. (2005). Early childhood education birth to 8: The world of children, families and educators (3rd ed). Boston, Pearson EducationGoogle Scholar
  21. Ferguson N. (1999). The pity of war. New York, Basic BooksGoogle Scholar
  22. Finer S. (1988). The man on horseback: The role of the military in politics. Boulder, Colorado, Westview PressGoogle Scholar
  23. Glaeser E., LaPorta R., Lopez-de-Silanes F., Shleifer A. (2004). Do institutions cause growth?. Journal of Economic Growth, 9, 271–303CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Glaeser, E., & Sacerdote, B. (2001). Education and religion, NBER Working Paper.Google Scholar
  25. Gordon A., Browne K. (2004). Beginnings and beyond: Foundations in early childhood education (6th ed). Clifton Park, NY, Thomson Delmar LearningGoogle Scholar
  26. Gradstein M., Justman M. (2002). Education, social cohesion, and economic growth. American Economic Review, 92, 1192–1204CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Hanson V. (2001). Carnage and Culture: Landmark battles in the rise of Western power. New York, DoubledayGoogle Scholar
  28. Helliwell, J., & Putnam, R. (2007). Education and social capital. Eastern Economics Journal (forthcoming).Google Scholar
  29. Holmes B. (1979). International guide to education systems. Paris, UNESCOGoogle Scholar
  30. Huntington S. (1957). The soldier and the state: The theory and politics of civil–military relations. Cambridge, Massachusetts, Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
  31. Huntington S. (1991). The third wave: Democratization in the late twentieth century. Norman, OK, University of Oklahoma PressGoogle Scholar
  32. Jaggers K., Marshall M. (2003). Polity IV project. Center for International Development and Conflict Management, University of MarylandGoogle Scholar
  33. Kamens D. (1988). Education and democracy: A comparative institutional analysis. Sociology of Education, 61, 114–127CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Keegan J. (1976). The face of battle. New York, Viking PressGoogle Scholar
  35. Lipset S.M. (1959). Some social requisites for democracy: Economic development and political legitimacy. American Political Science Review, 53, 69–105CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Lipset S.M. (1960). Political man: The social basis of modern politics. New York, DoubledayGoogle Scholar
  37. Milligan K., Moretti E., Oreopoulous P. (2004). Does education improve citizenship? Evidence from the US and the UK. Journal of Public Economics, 88, 1667–1695CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Mulligan C., Gil R., Sala-i-Martin X. (2004). Do democracies have different public policies than non-democracies?. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18, 51–74CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Mulligan C., Shleifer A. (2005). The extent of the market and the supply of regulation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120, 1445–1473CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Olson M. (1965). The logic of collective action: Public goods and the theory of groups. Cambridge, Massachusetts, Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
  41. Papaioannou E., Siourounis G. (2005). Economic and social factors driving the third wave of democratization. Mimeo, London Business SchoolGoogle Scholar
  42. Przeworski A., Limongi F. (1993). Political regimes and economic growth. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7, 51–70Google Scholar
  43. Przeworski A., Alvarez M., Cheibub J., Limongi F. (2000). Democracy and development: Political institutions and well-being in the world, 1950–1990. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
  44. Rander-Pehrson J.D. (1999). Germany and the revolution of 1848–1849. New York, Peter LangGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2007

Authors and Affiliations

  • Edward L. Glaeser
    • 1
  • Giacomo A. M. Ponzetto
    • 2
  • Andrei Shleifer
    • 1
    • 2
  1. 1.Harvard University and NBERCambridgeUSA
  2. 2.Department of EconomicsHarvard UniversityCambridgeUSA

Personalised recommendations