Journal of Cultural Economics

, Volume 40, Issue 4, pp 413–451 | Cite as

City competition for the creative class

Original Article

Abstract

This paper explores the conditions under which decentralization and fiscal competition lead to a policy of providing public amenities in order to attract highly productive labor. It provides a theoretical analysis which shows that the incentive to provide such amenities is particularly strong, if institutional restrictions prevent local governments from adjusting their tax structure. The empirical analysis considers the case of Germany, where public subsidies to local theaters are shown to exert a compensating earnings differential for highly educated labor. Taking account of the institutional setting, our empirical results suggest that local jurisdictions in Germany are subject to a substantial fiscal incentive to subsidize cultural activities.

Keywords

Fiscal competition Creative class Cultural amenities Theater subsidies Tax autonomy Capitalization Individual earnings 

JEL Classification

H76 Z18 H41 R13 

References

  1. Albouy, D. (2009). The unequal geographic burden of federal taxation. Journal of Political Economy, 117, 635–667.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Arntz, M. (2011). Mobilitaetshemmnisse heterogener Arbeitskraefte in Deutschland. Journal for Labour Market Research, 44, 135–141.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Bakhshi, H., Lee, N., & Mateos-Garcia, J. (2013). Capital of culture? An econometric analysis of the relationship between arts and cultural clusters, wages, and the creative economy in English cities. In M. Rushton (Ed.), Creative communities: Art works in economic development. Washington: Brookings.Google Scholar
  4. Blomquist, G. C., Berger, M. C., & Hoehn, J. P. (1988). New estimates of quality of life in urban areas. The American Economic Review, 78, 89–107.Google Scholar
  5. Borck, R. (2005). Fiscal competition, capital-skill complementarity, and the composition of public spending. Finanzarchiv, 61, 488–499.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Brueckner, J. K., Thisse, J.-F., & Zenou, Y. (1999). Why is central Paris rich and downtown Detroit poor?: An amenity-based theory. European Economic Review, 43, 91–107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Buettner, T. (2006). The incentive effect of fiscal equalization transfers on tax policy. Journal of Public Economics, 90, 477–497.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Buettner, T., & Ebertz, A. (2009). Quality of life in the regions: Results for German counties. The Annals of Regional Science, 43, 89–112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Carlino, G. A., & Saiz, A. (2008). City beautiful. IZA discussion paper. No. 3778.Google Scholar
  10. Chamberlain, G. (1994). Quantile regression, censoring, and the structure of wages. In: Sims, C., (ed.), Advances in Econo-metrics: Sixth world congress. Econometric Society Monograph, Volume 1, New York.Google Scholar
  11. Clark, D. E., & Kahn, J. R. (1988). The social benefits of urban cultural amenities. Journal of Regional Science, 28(3), 363–377.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Dustmann, C., & Glitz, A. (2011). Migration and Education, in Hanushek, Machin, Woessmann (eds). Handbook of the Economics of Education IV, 327-441.Google Scholar
  13. Eeckhout, J., Pinheiro, R., & Schmidheiny, K. (2014). Spatial sorting. Journal of Political Economy, 122(3), 554–620.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Falck, O., Fritsch, M., & Heblich, S. (2011). The phantom of the opera: Cultural amenities, human capital, and regional economic growth. Labour Economics, 18, 755–766.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Fassbender, H. & Kluge, J. (2006). Perspektive Deutschland: Was die Deutschen wirklich wollen, Berlin.Google Scholar
  16. Florida, R. (2002). The rise of the creative class. New York City: Basic Books.Google Scholar
  17. Glaeser, E. (2005). Review of richard Florida’s the rise of the creative class. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 35, 593–596.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Glaeser, E. L., & Mare, D. C. (2001). Cities and skills. Journal of Labor Economics, 9, 316–342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Keen, M., & Marchand, M. (1997). Fiscal competition and the pattern of public spending. Journal of Public Economics, 66, 33–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Krebs, S., & Pommerehne, W. W. (1995). Politico-economic interactions of German public performing arts institutions. Journal of Cultural Economics, 19(1), 17–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Lehmer, F., & Moeller, J. (2010). Interrelations between the urban wage premium and firm-size wage differentials a micro data cohort analysis for Germany. Annals of Regional Science, 45, 31–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Mansoorian, A., & Myers, G. M. (1993). Attachment to home and efficient purchases of population in a fiscal externality economy. Journal of Public Economics, 52, 117–132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Moretti, E. (2004). Workers’ education, spillovers and productivity: Evidence from plant-level production functions. American Economic Review, 94, 656–690.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. National Endowment for the Arts (2000). International data on government spending on the arts, Research Division Note #74, January.Google Scholar
  25. Oates, W. E. (1989). On the measurement of congestion in the provision of local public goods. Journal of Urban Economics, 24, 85–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Roback, J. (1982). Wages, rents, and the quality of life. Journal of Political Economy, 90, 1257–1278.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Rosen, S. (1974). Hedonic prices and implicit markets: Product differentiation in pure competition. Journal of Political Economy, 82, 34–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Russell, M. (1979). Comments on art subsidy: Distribution effects and the public purse. Journal of Cultural Economics, 4, 75–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Schulze, G. G., & Rose, A. (1998). Public orchestra funding in Germany: An empirical investigation. Journal of Cultural Economics, 22, 227–247.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Seaman, B. A. (1979). Local subsidization of culture: A public choice model based in household utility maximization. Journal of Behavioral Economics, 8, 93–131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Slemrod, J. (2004). Are corporate tax rates, or countries, converging? Journal of Public Economics, 88, 1169–1186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Thompson, E., Berger, M., Blomquist, G., & Allen, S. (2002). Valuing the arts: A contingent valuation approach. Journal of Cultural Economics, 26, 87–113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Traub, S., & Missong, M. (2005). On the public provision of performing arts. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 35, 862–882.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Wellisch, D. (2000). Theory of Public Finance in a Federal State. Cambridge Mass: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Wildasin, D. E. (1987). Theoretical analysis of local public economics. Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics II. North-Holland: Amsterdam, 1131–1178.Google Scholar
  36. Wilson, John D. (1986). A theory of interregional tax competition. Journal of Urban Economics, 19, 296–315.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Zodrow, George, & Mieszkowski, Peter. (1986). Pigeou, tiebout, property taxation and the underprovision of local public goods. Journal of Urban Economics, 19, 356–370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media New York 2015

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.University of Erlangen-NurembergNurembergGermany
  2. 2.Department of EconomicsUniversity of MannheimMannheimGermany

Personalised recommendations