Springer Nature is making SARS-CoV-2 and COVID-19 research free. View research | View latest news | Sign up for updates

Municipal elections and cultural expenditure

Abstract

The aim of this paper is to analyze the effect of electoral timing on municipal public cultural spending. We use a panel sample of all municipalities from the Spanish Region of Murcia for 1995–2008. Our results reveal that mayors adopt an opportunistic behavior, increasing cultural spending in the election year and reducing it in the second year after the election. We also investigate whether the electoral cycle in cultural spending is influenced by mayors’ ideology, political strength, willingness to run for re-election, and electoral competitiveness. In this regard, our study shows that when mayors expect close elections, political budget cycles’ size is greater. Concerning political leadership, the magnitude of the electoral cycle is influenced by mayors’ political ideology rather than mayors’ political strength and re-election willingness. Additionally, we seek to shed some light on the determinants of public cultural spending. We find that income and upper-level governments’ transfers have a positive impact on cultural spending. Finally, unemployment, young people’s proportion and elderly people’s proportion negatively influence cultural spending.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in to check access.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Notes

  1. 1.

    Source: Spanish Ministry of Culture database.

  2. 2.

    See Baltagi (2001).

  3. 3.

    Elections dates: in May 1995, June 1999, May 2003 and May 2007. Elections were always held on the same day for all municipalities.

Abbreviations

PBC:

Political budget cycles

References

  1. Aaberge, R., & Langørgen, A. (2003). Fiscal and spending behaviour of local governments: Identification of price effects when prices are not observed. Public Choice, 117(1–2), 125–161.

  2. Aidt, T., Veiga, F., & Veiga, L. (2011). Election results and opportunistic policies: A new test of the rational political business cycle model. Public Choice, 148(1–2), 21–44.

  3. Alesina, A. (1987). Macroeconomic policy in a two-party system as a repeated game. Quarterly Journal of Economics., 102(3), 651–678.

  4. Alesina, A. (1988). Macroeconomics and politics, NBER macroeconomics annual. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

  5. Alesina, A., & Rosenthal, H. (1995). Partisan politics, divided governments, and the economy. New York: Cambridge University Press.

  6. Allers, M., De Haan, J., & Sterks, C. (2001). Partisan influence on the local tax burden in the Netherlands. Public Choice, 106(3–4), 351–363.

  7. Alt, J. E., & Lowry, R. C. (1994). Divided government, fiscal institutions, and budget deficits: Evidence from the States. The American Political Science Review, 88(4), 811–828.

  8. Alt, J. E, & Rose, S. S. (2007). Context-conditional political budget cycles. In C. Boix, S. Stokes (Eds.) The oxford handbook of comparative politics. Oxford: Oxford University Press (in press).

  9. Anderson, T. W., & Hsiao, C. (1981). Estimation of dynamic models with error components. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 76, 598–606.

  10. Anderson, T. W., & Hsiao, C. (1982). Formulation and estimation of dynamic models using panel data. Journal of Econometrics, 18, 47–82.

  11. Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Review of Economics and Statistics, 58(2), 277–297.

  12. Ashworth, J., Geys, B., & Heyndels, B. (2005). Government weakness and local public debt development in Flemish municipalities. International Tax and Public Finance, 12(4), 395–422.

  13. Balerias, R., & Costa, S. (2004). To be or not to be in office again. An empirical test of a local political business cycle rationale. European Journal of Political Economy, 20(3), 655–671.

  14. Baltagi, B. H. (2001). Econometric analysis of panel data (2nd ed.). Chichester: Wiley.

  15. Besley, T., & Case, A. (1995). Does electoral accountability affect economic policy choices? Evidence from gubernatorial term limits? Quarterly Journal of Economics., 110(3), 769–798.

  16. Bille Hansen, T. (1997). The willingness-to-pay for the Royal Theatre in Copenhagen as a public good. Journal of Cultural Economics, 21(1), 1–28.

  17. Blais, A., & Nadeau, R. (1992). The electoral budget cycle. Public Choice, 74(4), 389–403.

  18. Borge, L., Rattsø, J., & Sørensen, R. (1995). Local government service production: The Politics of allocative sluggishness. Public Choice, 82(1–2), 135–157.

  19. Brooks, A. C. (2001). Who opposes government arts funding? Public Choice, 108(3–4), 355–367.

  20. Brooks, A. C. (2003). Public opinion and the role of government arts funding in Spain. Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis: Research and Practice, 5(1), 29–38.

  21. Cárdenas, O. J., & Sharma, A. (2011). Mexican municipalities and the flypaper effect. Public Budgeting & Finance, 31(3), 73–93.

  22. Cusack, T. R. (1997). Partisan politics and public finance: Changes in public spending in the industrialized democracies, 1955–1989. Public Choice, 91(3–4), 375–395.

  23. Dezhbakhsh, H., Tohamy, S. M., & Aranson, P. H. (2003). A new approach for testing budgetary incrementalism. Journal of Politics, 65(2), 532–558.

  24. DiMaggio, P., & Pettit, B. (1999). Public opinion and political vulnerability: Why has the national endowment for the arts been such an attractive target? Working paper. Princeton University, Center for Arts and Cultural Policy Studies.

  25. DiMaggio, P., & Useem, M. (1978). Cultural democracy in a period of cultural expansion: the social composition of arts audiences in the United States. Social Problems, 26, 180–197.

  26. Drazen, A. (2008a). Political business cycles. In S. N. Durlauf & L. E. Blume (Eds.), The new palgrave dictionary of economics. Palgrave Macmillan, 2008, The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Online, Palgrave Macmillan. 03 July 2012, doi:10.1057/9780230226203.1298.

  27. Drazen, A. (2008b). Political budget cycles. In S. N. Durlauf & L. E. Blume (Eds.), The new palgrave dictionary of economics. Palgrave Macmillan, 2008, The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Online, Palgrave Macmillan. 03 July 2012, doi:10.1057/9780230226203.1297.

  28. Drazen, A., & Eslava, M. (2010). Electoral manipulation via voter-friendly spending. Theory and evidence. Journal of Development Economics, 92(1), 39–52.

  29. Foucault, M., Thierry, M., & Paty, S. (2008). Public spending interactions and local politics. Empirical evidence from French municipalities. Public Choice, 137(1–2), 57–80.

  30. Franzese, R., & Jusko, K. L. (2006). Political-economic cycles. In D. Wittman & B. Weingast (Eds.), Oxford handbook of political economy (pp. 545–564). New York: Oxford UP.

  31. Frey, B. (2003). Public support. In R. Towse (Ed.), A handbook of cultural economics (pp. 389–398). UK/Lyme, US: Cheltenham/Edward Elgar.

  32. Fullerton, D. (1991). On justifications for public support of the arts. Journal of Cultural Economics, 15(2), 67–82.

  33. Getzner, M. (2002). Determinants of public cultural expenditures: an exploratory time series analysis for Austria. Journal of Cultural Economics, 26(4), 287–306.

  34. Getzner, M. (2004). Exploring voter preferences in cultural policy: a case study for Austria. Empirica, 31(1), 27–42.

  35. Geys, B. (2007). Government weakness and electoral cycles in local public debt: evidence from Flemish municipalities. Local Government Studies, 33(2), 237–251.

  36. Golden, D., & Porteba, J. (1980). The price of popularity: The political business cycle Reexamined. American Journal of Political Science, 24(4), 696–714.

  37. Grampp, W. D. (1989). Rent-seeking in arts policy. Public Choice, 60(2), 113–121.

  38. Gray, C. (2009). Managing cultural policy: Pitfalls and prospects. Public Administration, 87(3), 574–585.

  39. Hibbs, D. (1977). Political parties and macro-economic policy. American Political Science Review, 71(4), 1467–1487.

  40. Hibbs, D. A. (1987). The political economy of industrial democracy. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

  41. Jones, B. D., True, J. L., & Baumgartner, F. R. (1997). Does incrementalism stem from political consensus or from institutional gridlock? American Journal of Political Science, 41(4), 1319–1339.

  42. Kneebone, R., & McKenzie, K. (2001). Electoral and partisan cycles in fiscal policy: An examination of Canadian provinces. International Tax and Public Finance, 8(5–6), 753–774.

  43. Krebs, S., & Pommerehne, W. W. (1995). Politico-economic interactions of German public performing arts institutions. Journal of Cultural Economics, 19(1), 17–32.

  44. Kushner, J., Masse, I., Peters, T., & Soroka, L. (1996). The determinants of municipal expenditures in Ontario. Canadian Tax Journal, 44(2), 451–464.

  45. Lewis, G., & Rushton, M. (2007). Understanding state spending on the arts, 1976–99. State and Local Government Review, 39(2), 107–114.

  46. Nogare, C. D., & Galizzi, M. M. (2011). The political economy of cultural spending: evidence from Italian cities. Journal of Cultural Economics, 35(3), 203–231.

  47. Noonan, D. (2007). Fiscal pressures, institutional context, and constituents: A dynamic model of states’ art agency appropriations. Journal of Cultural Economics, 31(4), 293–310.

  48. Nordhaus, W. (1975). The political business cycle. Review of Economic Studies, 42(2), 169–190.

  49. Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (1990). Macroeconomic policy, credibility and politics. New York NY: Harwood Academic Publishers.

  50. Potrafke, N. (2010). Ideology and cultural policy. Working paper.

  51. Potrafke, N. (2011). Public expenditures on education and cultural affairs in the West German states: does government ideology influence the budget composition? German Economic Review, 12(1), 124–145.

  52. Real Instituto Elcano (Estudios Internacionales y Estratégicos). (2004). Cultural policy in Spain. http://www.realinstitutoelcano.org/documentos/110/IN040428.pdf.

  53. Rogoff, K. (1990). Equilibrium political budget cycles. The American Economic Review, 80(1), 21–36.

  54. Rogoff, K., & Sibert, A. (1988). Elections and macroeconomic policy cycles. The Review of Economic Studies, 55(1), 1–16.

  55. Roodman, D. (2009). A note on the theme of too many instruments. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 71(1), 135–158.

  56. Rose, S. (2006). Do fiscal rules dampen the political business cycle? Public Choice, 128(3–4), 407–431.

  57. Rose, S. (2008). The political manipulation of US state rainy day funds under rules versus discretion. State Politics & Policy Quarterly, 8(2), 150–176.

  58. Rosenberg, J. (1992). Rationality and the political business cycle: The case of local Government. Public Choice, 73(1), 71–81.

  59. Roubini, N., & Sachs, J. D. (1989). Political and economic determinants of budget deficits in the industrial democracies. European Economic Review, 33(5), 903–933.

  60. Rushton, M. (2005). Support for earmarked public spending on culture: Evidence from a referendum in metropolitan Detroit. Public Budgeting and Finance, 25(4), 72–85.

  61. Schulze, G., & Rose, A. (1998). Public orchestra funding in Germany: An empirical investigation. Journal of Cultural Economics, 22(4), 227–247.

  62. Schulze, G. G., & Ursprung, H. W. (2000). La Donna e mobile—or is she? Voter preferences and public support for the performing arts. Public Choice, 102(1–2), 129–147.

  63. Seitz, H. (2000). Fiscal policy, deficits and politics of subnational governments: The case of the German Laender. Public Choice, 102(3–4), 183–218.

  64. Shi, M., & Svensson, J. (2002). Conditional political budget cycles. CEPR discussion paper, no. 3352.

  65. Shi, M., & Svensson, J. (2004). Political budget cycles: A review of recent developments. Nordic Journal of Political Economy, 29(1), 67–76.

  66. Stastna, L. (2009). Spatial interdependence of local public expenditures: Selected evidence from the czech republic. Czech Economic Review, 3(1), 7–25.

  67. Tellier, G. (2006). Public expenditures in Canadian provinces: An empirical study of politicoeconomic interactions. Public Choice, 126(3–4), 367–385.

  68. Throsby, D. (1994). The production and consumption of the arts. Journal of Economic Literature, 32(1), 1–29.

  69. Throsby, C. D., & Withers, G. A. (1986). Strategic bias and demand for public goods: Theory and an application to the arts. Journal of Public Economics, 31(3), 307–327.

  70. Tiebout, C. M. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditure. Journal of Political Economy, 64, 416–424.

  71. Tufte, E. R. (1978). Political control of the economy. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.

  72. Van der Ploeg, F. (2006). The making of cultural policy: A European perspective. In V. Ginsburgh & D. Throsby (Eds.), Handbook of the Economics of Art and Culture (pp. 1183–1221). Amsterdam: North-Holland.

  73. Veiga, L. G., & Veiga, F. J. (2007). Political business cycles at the municipal level. Public Choice, 131(1–2), 45–64.

  74. Von Hagen, J. (2006). Fiscal rules and fiscal performance in the European Union and Japan. Monetary and Economic Studies, 24, 25–60.

  75. Wagner, A. (1958). Three extracts on public finance. In R. Musgrave & A. T. Peacock (Eds.), Classics in the theory of public finance (pp. 1–16). London: Macmillan.

  76. Werck, K., Heyndels, B., & Geys, B. (2008). The impact of ‘central places’ on spatial spending patterns: Evidence from Flemish local government cultural expenditures. Journal of Cultural Economics, 32(1), 35–58.

  77. Wert, M. (2006). The political economy of the subsidization of cultural institutions: Empirical evidence from Germany. Working paper.

  78. Withers, G. (1979). Private demand for public subsidies: An econometric study of cultural support in Australia. Journal of Cultural Economics, 3(1), 53–61.

Download references

Acknowledgment

This study has benefited from the financial support of the Spanish National R & D Plan through the research projects ECO2010-17463 and ECO2010-20522 (Ministry of Science and Innovation).

Author information

Correspondence to Bernardino Benito.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and Permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Benito, B., Bastida, F. & Vicente, C. Municipal elections and cultural expenditure. J Cult Econ 37, 3–32 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10824-012-9175-5

Download citation

Keywords

  • Electoral cycles
  • Cultural spending
  • Local governments

JEL Classification

  • H76