Advertisement

Journal of Bioeconomics

, Volume 14, Issue 2, pp 101–114 | Cite as

Evolvability and progress in evolutionary economics

  • Tim Cochrane
  • James MaclaurinEmail author
Article

Abstract

This paper develops an account of evolutionary progress for use in the field of evolutionary economics. Previous work is surveyed and a new account set out, based on the idea of evolvability as it has been used recently in evolutionary developmental biology. The biological underpinnings of this idea are explained using examples of a series of phenomena that influence the evolvability of biological systems. It is further argued that biological and economic selection pressures and developmental processes are sufficiently similar to make this biological concept useful in economics. The new account is defended against a number of common objections to the notion of progress in evolving systems, including the claim that all stipulated measures of evolutionary progress are essentially arbitrary and the idea that economic evolutionary progress might not accord with the preferences of economic actors. It is argued that progress, understood as an increase in evolvability over time, is both philosophically well-justified and provides useful predictive and explanatory resources to those seeking to understand and manipulate evolving economic systems.

Keywords

Progress Evolvability Modularity Entrenchment Change 

JEL Classification

B25 B52 

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Allen P. M. (2005) Understanding social and economic systems as evolutionary complex systems. In: Dopfer K. (eds) The evolutionary foundations of economics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 431–460CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Arthur W. B. (1989) Competing technologies, increasing returns, and lock-in by historical events. Economic Journal 99: 116–131CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Baumol W. J. (2004) Red-queen games: Arms races, rule of law and market economies. Journal of Evolutionary Economics 14: 237–247CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Boulding K. E. (1991) What is evolutionary economics?. Journal of Evolutionary Economics 1: 9–17CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Bryant K. (2001) Promoting innovation: An overview of the application of evolutionary economics and systems approaches to policy issues. In: Foster J., Metcalfe J. S. (eds) Frontiers of evolutionary economics: Competition, self-organization and innovation policy. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 361–384Google Scholar
  6. Buenstrof G. (2007) Creation and pursuit of entrepreneurial opportunities: An evolutionary economics perspective. Small Business Economics 28: 323–337CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Campbell D. T. (1965) Variation and selective retention in socio-cultural evolution. In: Barringer H. R., Blanksten G. I., Mack R. W. (eds) Social change in developing areas: A reinterpretation of evolutionary theory. Schenkman, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
  8. Costanza, R., Hart, M., Posner, S., & Talberth, J. (2009). Beyond GDP: The Need for New Measures of Progress. The Pardee Papers, (4), 1–46. Boston: Boston University.Google Scholar
  9. David P. A. (1985) Clio and the Economics of QWERTY. American Economic Review 75(2): 332–337Google Scholar
  10. David P.A. (2000) Path dependence and varieties of learning in the evolution of technological practice. In: Ziman J. (eds) Technological innovation as an evolutionary process. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  11. Dawkins R. (1982) The extended phenotype. Oxford University Press, OxfordGoogle Scholar
  12. Dawkins R. (1989) The evolution of evolvability. In: Langton C. G. (eds) Artificial life. Addison Wesley Publishing Company, Los Alamos, pp 201–220Google Scholar
  13. Day R. H., Walter J. (1989) Economic growth in the very long run: On the multiple-phase interaction of population, technology, and social infrastructure. In: Barnett W. A., Geweke J., Shell K. (eds) Economic complexity, chaos, sunspots, bubbles, and nonlinearity. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 253–289Google Scholar
  14. Dosi G., Nelson R. R. (1994) An introduction to evolutionary theories in economics. Journal of Evolutionary Economics 4: 153–172CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Douglas W. O., Shanks C. M. (1929) Insulation from liability through subsidiary corporations. The Yale Law Journal 39(2): 193–218CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Eldrege N., Gould S.J. (1972) Punctuated Equilibria: An alternative to phyletic gradualism. In: Schopf T.J.M. (eds) Models of Paleobiology. Freeman, Cooper and Co, San Francisco, Calif, pp 82–115Google Scholar
  17. Ghiselin M. T. (1999) Progress and the economy of nature. Journal of Bioeconomics 1: 35–45CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Gould, S. J., & Lewontin, R. C. (1979). Evolution: The spandrels of San Marco and the Panglossian paradigm: A critique of the adaptationist programme. Proceedings of the Royal Society of London, Series B, 205(1161), 581–598.Google Scholar
  19. Gould S.J., Vrba E. (1982) Exaptation: A Missing Term in the Science of Form. Paleobiology 8(1): 4–15Google Scholar
  20. Gowdy J. M. (1985) Evolutionary theory and economic theory: Some methodological issues. Review of Social Economy 43(3): 316–324CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Gowdy J. M. (1997) Introduction: Biology and economics. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 8(4): 377–383CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Griswold C. K. (2006) Pleiotropic mutation, modularity and evolvability. Evolution and Development 8(1): 81–93CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Halpern P., Trebilcock M., Turnbull S.M. (1980) An economic analysis of limited liability in corporate law. University of Toronto Law Journal 30: 117–150CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Hermann-Pillath C. (2004) On the ontological foundations of evolutionary economics. In: Dopfer K. (eds) The evolutionary foundations of economics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 89–139Google Scholar
  25. Hernandez I., Dewick P. (2003) Structural change and the nature of innovative activity: Legal form and firm performance. Innovation: Management, Policy & Practice 5: 257–269CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Hirshleifer J. (1982) Evolutionary models in economics and law: Cooperation versus conflict strategies. Research in Law and Economics 4: 1–60Google Scholar
  27. Hodgson G. M. (2002) Darwinism in economics: From analogy to continuity. Journal of Evolutionary Economics 12(3): 259–281CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Hodgson G. M., Knudsen T. (2006) The nature and units of social selection. Journal of Evolutionary Economics 16: 477–489CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Kingston W. (2006) Schumpeter, business cycles and co-evolution. Industry and Innovation 13(1): 97–106CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Kirchgässner G. (1994) Constitutional economics and its relevance for the evolution of rules. Kyklos 47(3): 321–339CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Kirschner M. W., Gerhart J., Norton J. (2005) The plausibility of life: Resolving Darwin’s dilemma. Yale University Press, New HavenGoogle Scholar
  32. Kondratieff N. D. (1935) The long waves in economic life. Review of Economic Statistics 17(6): 105–115CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Levin P. (2001) The market process and the economics of QWERTY: Two views. Review of Austrian Economics 14: 65–96CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Levins R., Lewontin R. (1985) The dialectical biologist. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
  35. Lewontin R. (1970) The units of selection. Annual Review of Ecology and Systematics 1: 1–18CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Liebowitz S. J., Margolis E. (1990) The fable of the keys. Journal of Law and Economics 33: 1–25CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Lipshaw J. M. (2009) The epistemology of the financial crisis. Southern California Interdisciplinary Law Journal 19(2): 299–351Google Scholar
  38. Markose S. M. (2005) Computability and evolutionary complexity: Markets as complex adaptive systems (CAS). Economic Journal 115(504): F159–F192CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Maynard Smith J., Szathmáry E. (1995) The major transitions in evolution. Freeman, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  40. McShea D. (1991) Complexity and evolution: What everybody knows. Biology and Philosophy 6: 303–324CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. McShea D. (1996) Metazoan complexity and evolution: Is there a trend?. Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review 50: 477–492Google Scholar
  42. Metcalfe J. S. (1989) Evolution and economic change. In: Silberston A. (eds) Technology and economic change. MacMillan, Basingstoke, pp 54–85Google Scholar
  43. Metcalfe J. S. (2001) Institutions and progress. Industrial and Corporate Change 10(3): 561–586CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Metcalfe J. S. (2005) Evolutionary concepts in relation to evolutionary economics. In: Dopfer K. (eds) The evolutionary foundations of economics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 391–430CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Metcalfe J. S., Foster J., Ramlogan R. (2006) Adaptive economic growth. Cambridge Journal of Economics 30: 7–32CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  46. Morgan B. (2001) The origins of successful economic organizations. In: Foster J., Metcalfe J. S. (eds) Frontiers of evolutionary economics: Competition, self-organization and innovation policy. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 152–159Google Scholar
  47. Nelson R. R. (1994) Economic growth via the co-evolution of technology and institutions. In: Leydesdorff L., van den Besselaar P. (eds) Evolutionary economics and chaos theory: New developments in technology studies. Pinter, London, pp 21–32Google Scholar
  48. Nelson R. R. (2001) The coevolution of technology and institutions as the driver of economic growth. In: Foster J., Metcalfe J. S. (eds) Frontiers of evolutionary economics: Competition, self-organization and innovation policy. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 19–30Google Scholar
  49. Nitecki, M. H. (eds) (1988) Evolutionary progress. University of Chicago Press, ChicagoGoogle Scholar
  50. Nooteboom B. (2001) From evolution to language and learning. In: Foster J., Metcalfe J. S. (eds) Frontiers of evolutionary economics: Competition, self-organization and innovation policy. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 41–69Google Scholar
  51. North D. C. (1996) Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  52. Nussbaum M. C. (2000) Women and human development: The capabilities approach. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  53. Okasha S. (2006) Evolution and the levels of selection. Oxford University Press, OxfordCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  54. Pigliucci M. (2008) Is evolvability evolvable?. Nature Reviews Genetics 9(1): 75–82CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  55. Rawls J. (1970) A theory of justice. Harvard University Press, BostonGoogle Scholar
  56. Ridley M. (1994) The Red Queen: Sex and the evolution of human nature. Harper, LondonGoogle Scholar
  57. Robson A. J. (2005) Complex evolutionary systems and the Red Queen. Economic Journal 115(504): F211–F224CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  58. Roe M. (1993) Some differences in corporate structure in Germany, Japan, and the United States. The Yale Law Review 102: 1927–2003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  59. Rosenberg A., McShea D. (2008) Philosophy of biology. Routledge, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  60. Ruse M. (1996) Monad to man: The concept of progress in evolutionary biology. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
  61. Schank, J. C., & Wimsatt, W. C. (1986). Generative entrenchment and evolution. PSA: Proceedings of the Biennial Meeting of the Philosophy of Science Association, 2, 33–60.Google Scholar
  62. Schank J. C., Wimsatt W. C. (2001) Evolvability: Adaptation and modularity. In: Singh R. S., Krimbas C. B., Paul D. B., Beatty J. (eds) Thinking about evolution. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 322–335Google Scholar
  63. Schumpeter J. (1928) The instability of capitalism. Economic Journal 38: 361–386CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  64. Schumpeter J. A. (1939) Business cycles. McGraw-Hill, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  65. Sen A. K. (1985) Commodities and capabilities. Oxford University Press, OxfordGoogle Scholar
  66. Shanahan T. (2004) The evolution of Darwinism: Selection, adaptation and progress in evolutionary biology. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  67. Shiozawa Y. (2004) Evolutionary economics in the 21st century. Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review 1(2): 5–47Google Scholar
  68. Tawney R. H. (1961) The acquisitive society. Collins, LondonGoogle Scholar
  69. van den Bergh J. (2007) Evolutionary thinking in environmental economics. Journal of Evolutionary Economics 17: 521–549CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  70. van den Bergh J.C.J.M. (2009) The GDP Paradox. Journal of Economic Psychology 30: 117–135CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  71. van Valen L. (1973) A new evolutionary law. Evolutionary Theory 1(1): 11–30Google Scholar
  72. Vrba E. (1984) What is species selection?. Systematic Zoology 33: 318–328CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  73. Wagner G.P., Mezey J.G. (2004) The role of genetic architecture constraints for the origin of variational modularity. In: Schlosser G., Wagner G.P. (eds) Modularity in Development and Evolution. Chicago University Press, Chicago, IL, pp 338–358Google Scholar
  74. Wagner G., Altenberg L. (1996) Complex adaptations and the evolution of evolvability. Evolution 50(3): 967–976CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  75. West-Eberhard M. J. (2003) Developmental plasticity and evolution. Oxford University Press, OxfordGoogle Scholar
  76. Wilkins J. S. (2001) The appearance of Lamarckism in the evolution of culture. In: Nightingale J., Laurent J. (eds) Darwinism and evolutionary economics. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 160–183Google Scholar
  77. Wimsatt W. C. (2007) Re-engineering philosophy for limited beings. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
  78. Witt U. (1996) Innovations, externalities and the problem of economic progress. Public Choice 89: 113–130CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  79. Witt U. (1999) Bioeconomics as economics from a Darwinian perspective. Journal of Bioeconomics 1: 19–34CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC. 2011

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.University of OtagoDunedinNew Zealand

Personalised recommendations