Advertisement

Unilateral introduction of destination-based cash-flow taxation

  • Johannes BeckerEmail author
  • Joachim Englisch
Article
  • 17 Downloads

Abstract

We analyze the unilateral introduction of a destination-based corporate cash-flow tax system (DBT), as proposed by Auerbach and Devereux (AEJ Policy 2018). We show that, first, the DBT rate is decision-neutral only if the source tax country makes the DBT payments deductible from its tax base. Second, a unilateral DBT introduction is, in many aspects, equivalent to completely abolishing the corporate tax and, instead, taxing domestic investors based upon their worldwide profit income, net of foreign taxes and on accrual. In this sense, the DBT is actually a pure residence-based tax. This implies that, from a foreign investor’s perspective, the DBT country is like a zero-rate tax haven and has the same gravitational power on taxable profits and economic activity. Third, the location of profit and activity within its borders is, however, without any fiscal value for the DBT country. Fourth, the introduction of a DBT system reduces national income. Fifth, the DBT country can only individually benefit from its new tax system if public goods provision is substantially increased. Finally, it is optimal to complement a unilateral DBT system with a source-based tax.

Keywords

Business taxation Destination taxation Tax competition 

JEL classification

H25 H32 H87 

Notes

Acknowledgements

We thank referees as well as participants of the 2017 Summer Symposium of the Oxford University Centre for Business Taxation and the CESifo Venice Summer Institute 2018 for helpful comments.

References

  1. Auerbach, A. J., & Devereux, M. P. (2018). Cash-Flow Taxes in an International Setting. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 10(3), 69–94.Google Scholar
  2. Auerbach, A. J., Devereux, M. P., Keen, M., & Vella, J. (2017a). Destination-based cash flow taxation. Oxford University Centre for Business Taxation WP 17/01.Google Scholar
  3. Auerbach, A. J., Devereux, M. P., Keen, M., & Vella, J. (2017b). International tax planning under the destination-based cash flow tax. National Tax Journal, 70(4), 783–802.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Auerbach, A. J., Devereux, M. P., & Simpson, H. (2010). Taxing corporate income. In J. Mirrlees, et al. (Eds.), Dimensions of tax design: The Mirrlees Review (pp. 837–893). Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  5. Avi-Yonah, R. S. (2000). Globalization, tax competition, and the fiscal crisis of the welfare state. Harvard Law Review, 113, 1573–1676.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Avi-Yonah, R. S., & Clausing, K. (2017). Problems with destination-based corporate taxes and the Ryan blueprint, Working paper.Google Scholar
  7. Barbiero, O., Farhi, E., Gopinath, G., & Itskhoki, O. (2018). The macroeconomics of border taxes. In: NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2018, Vol. 33. Eichenbaum and Parker.Google Scholar
  8. Becker, J., & Englisch, J. (2017). A European perspective on the US plans for a destination based cash flow tax. Oxford University Centre for Business Taxation Working Paper WP 17/03.Google Scholar
  9. Bond, E., & Gresik, T. (2019). Unilateral tax reform: Border adjusted taxes, cash flow taxes, and transfer pricing, Working Paper.Google Scholar
  10. Bond, S. R., & Devereux, M. P. (2002). Cash flow taxes in an open economy. CEPR Discussion Paper 3401.Google Scholar
  11. Buiter, W. (2017). Exchange rate implications of border tax adjustment neutrality, CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP 11885.Google Scholar
  12. Cui, W. (2017). Destination-based cash-flow taxation: a critical appraisal. University of Toronto Law Journal, 67(2), 301–347. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Devereux, M. P., & de la Feria, R. (2014). Designing and implementing a destination-based corporate tax. Oxford University Centre for Business Taxation WP 14/07.Google Scholar
  14. Feldstein, M. S., & Hartman, D. (1979). The optimal taxation of foreign source investment income. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 93(4), 613–629.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Freund, C., & Gagnon, J. E. (2017). Effects of consumption taxes on real exchange rates and trade balances. Peterson Institute for International Economics Working Paper 17-5.Google Scholar
  16. GOP. (2016). A better way—Our vision for a confident America, 24 June 2016.Google Scholar
  17. Graetz, M. J. (2017). The known unknowns of the business tax reforms proposed in the house republican blueprint. Columbia Journal of Tax Law, 8, 117–169.Google Scholar
  18. Grinberg, I. (2017). A destination-based cash flow tax can be structured to comply with world trade organization rules. National Tax Journal, 70, 803–818.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Hebous, A., & Klemm, A. (2018). A Destination-based allowance for corporate equity, CESifo Working Paper No. 7363.Google Scholar
  20. Hebous, S., Klemm, A., & Stausholm, S. (2019). Revenue implications of destination-based cash-flow taxation, CESifo Working Paper No. 7457.Google Scholar
  21. Lamensch, M. (2017). Destination based taxation of corporate profits—Preliminary findings regarding tax collection in cross-border situations. Oxford Centre for Business Taxation Working paper series (WP17/16).Google Scholar
  22. Miller, D. S. (2017). Tax planning under the destination based cash flow tax: A guide for policy makers and practitioners. Columbia Journal of Tax Law, 8, 295–306.Google Scholar
  23. Musgrave, P. B. (1969). United States taxation of foreign investment income: Issues and arguments. Cambridge, MA, International Tax Program, Harvard Law School.Google Scholar
  24. Richman, P. B. (1963). Taxation of foreign investment income—An economic analysis. Baltimore.Google Scholar
  25. Schön, W. (2016). Destination-based income taxation and WTO law: A note. Max planck institute for tax law and public finance working paper 2016—03.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC, part of Springer Nature 2019

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.University of MuensterMuensterGermany

Personalised recommendations