International Tax and Public Finance

, Volume 24, Issue 2, pp 179–197 | Cite as

Collusive tax evasion and social norms

  • Martin Abraham
  • Kerstin Lorek
  • Friedemann Richter
  • Matthias Wrede
Article
  • 480 Downloads

Abstract

Although collusive tax evasion by buyers and sellers of commodities and also by employers and employees is widespread all over the world, it has rarely been analyzed in the tax evasion literature. To fill this gap and to compare collusive tax evasion with independent tax evasion, this paper develops a simple noncooperative game-theoretic model and confirms the model’s predictions in a laboratory experiment. Because collusive tax evasion involves social interaction, this paper focuses on the effect of social norms and theoretically and empirically demonstrates that the tax compliance norm has a stronger negative effect on the magnitude of collusive tax evasion than on independent tax evasion. The reason for this result is that in a collusive tax evasion game with multiple equilibria social norms affect the range of equilibria and act as an equilibrium selection device, whereas social norms need to be strongly internalized to change the behavior of taxpayers who evade taxes unobservedly.

Keywords

Collusive tax evasion Third-party reporting Social norms 

JEL Classification

H26 A13 

Notes

Acknowledgments

We gratefully acknowledge the financial support from the FAUs Emerging Fields Initiative (University of Erlangen–Nürnberg). For providing the laboratory resources used in this study, we kindly thank LERN of the University of Erlangen–Nürnberg. The paper was presented at the Bavarian Public Economics Seminar 2014 in Munich, at the University of Rostock, at the 4th International Conference on The Shadow Economy, Tax Evasion and Governance 2015 in Exeter, and at the International Institute of Public Finance Conference 2015 in Dublin. The comments of the participants, especially Thiess Büttner and Markus Knell, and two anonymous referees of this journal are appreciated with gratitude.

Supplementary material

10797_2016_9417_MOESM1_ESM.pdf (119 kb)
Supplementary material 1 (pdf 119 KB)

References

  1. Abbink, K., & Hennig-Schmidt, H. (2006). Neutral versus loaded instructions in a bribery experiment. Experimental Economics, 9, 103–121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Acemoglu, D., & Jackson, M.O. (2014). Social norms and the enforcement of laws. Working Paper 20369, NBER.Google Scholar
  3. Bénabou, R., & Tirole, J. (2006). Incentives and prosocial behavior. American Economic Review, 96(5), 1652–1678.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Boadway, R., Marceau, N., & Mongrain, S. (2002). Joint tax evasion. Canadian Journal of Economics, 35, 417–435.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Chang, J.-J., & Lai, C.-C. (2004). Collaborative tax evasion and social norms: Why deterrence does not work. Oxford Economic Papers, 56, 344–368.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Coleman, J. (1987). Norms as social capital. In G. Radnitzky & P. Bernholz (Eds.), Economic imperialism: The economic approach applied outside the field of economics. New York: Paragon.Google Scholar
  7. CPB Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis (2013). Study to quantify and analyse the vat gap in the eu-27 member states final report. TAXUD/2012/DE/316, FWC No. TAXUD/2010/CC/104.Google Scholar
  8. Croson, R., & Gneezy, U. (2009). Gender differences in preferences. Journal of Economic Literature, 47, 448–474.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Ellingsen, T., Johannesson, M., Mollerstromb, J., & Munkhammar, S. (2012). Social framing effects: Preferences or beliefs? Games and Economic Behavior, 76, 117–130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Elster, J. (1989). Social norms and economic theory. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 3, 99–117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. EVS (2011). European values study 2008: Integrated dataset (evs 2008). ZA4800 Data file Version 3.0.0, GESIS Data Archive, Cologne.Google Scholar
  12. Feld, L.P., & Frey, B.S. (2006). Tax evasion in Switzerland: The roles of deterrence and tax morale. Available at SSRN 900351.Google Scholar
  13. Feld, L., & Larsen, C. (2012). Undeclared work, deterrence and social norms: The case of Germany. Berlin Heidelberg: Springer-Verlag.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10, 171–178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Fischbacher, U., & Gächter, S. (2010). Social preferences, beliefs, and the dynamics of free riding in public goods experiments. American Economic Review, 100(1), 541–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Fortin, B., Lacroix, G., & Villeval, M.-C. (2007). Tax evasion and social interactions. Journal of Public Economics, 91, 2089–2112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Frey, B. S., & Torgler, B. (2007). Tax morale and conditional cooperation. Journal of Comparative Economics, 35(1), 136–159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Gilligan, C. (1982). In a different voice: Psychological theory and women’s development. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  19. Gordon, J. P. F. (1989). Individual morality and reputation costs as deterrents to tax evasion. European Economic Review, 33, 797–805.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Greiner, B. (2004). The online recruitment system orsee 2.0 - a guide for the organization of experiments in economics. Working Paper Series in Economics 10, University of Cologne.Google Scholar
  21. Institut für Demoskopie Allensbach (2001). Moral 2001 - werte und normen im wandel. Allensbacher Berichte 10.Google Scholar
  22. Keen, M., & Smith, S. (2007). Vat fraud and evasion: What do we know, and what can be done? Working Paper 07/31, IMF.Google Scholar
  23. Kleven, H. J., Knudsen, M. B., Kreiner, C. T., Pedersen, S., & Saez, E. (2011). Unwilling or unable to cheat? Evidence from a tax audit experiment in Denmark. Econometrica, 79, 651–692.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Mears, D. P., Ploeger, M., & Warr, M. (1998). Explaining the gender gap in delinquency: Peer influence and moral evaluations of behavior. Journal of Research in Crime and Delinquency, 35, 251–266.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Schelling, T. C. (1960). The strategy of conflict. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  26. Schneider, F., & Enste, D. H. (2000). Shadow economies: Size, causes, and consequences. Journal of Economic Literature, 38, 77–114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Stiftung Marktwirtschaft (2010). Hintergrundinformationen zum pressegespräch der stiftung marktwirtschaft - guter staat - böse bürger? schattenwirtschaft und steuerhinterziehung. Tech. rep.Google Scholar
  28. Sutherland, E. H., Cressey, D. R., & Luckenbill, D. F. (1992). Principles of criminology (11th ed.). Philadelphia: Lippincott.Google Scholar
  29. Yaniv, G. (1992). Collaborated employee-employer tax evasion. Public Finance, 47, 312–321.Google Scholar
  30. Yaniv, G. (1998). Tax evasion by misinforming withholding agents. Public Finance Review, 26, 362–375.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Young, H. (2008). Social norms. In S. N. Durlauf & L. E. Blume (Eds.), The new Palgrave dictionary of economics (Vol. 7, pp. 647–651). Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media New York 2016

Authors and Affiliations

  • Martin Abraham
    • 1
  • Kerstin Lorek
    • 1
  • Friedemann Richter
    • 1
  • Matthias Wrede
    • 1
  1. 1.School of Business and EconomicsFriedrich-Alexander University Erlangen-Nürnberg (FAU)NürnbergGermany

Personalised recommendations